Principles of corporate finance H. Zhong, P. Frantz, R. Payne, J. Favilukis FN2191 2018 Undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences This subject guide is for a 200 course offered as part of the University of London undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social Sciences. This is equivalent to Level 5 within the Framework for Higher Education Qualifications in England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ). For more information, see: www.london.ac.uk This guide was prepared for the University of London by: Dr Hongda Zhong, Assistant Professor of Finance, The London of Economics and Political Science and Dr. J. Favilukis, Lecturer, The London School of Economics and Political Science This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due to pressure of work the authors are unable to enter into any correspondence relating to, or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or unfavourable, please use the form at the back of this guide. University of London Publications Office Stewart House 32 Russell Square London WC1B 5DN United Kingdom london.ac.uk Published by: University of London © University of London 2018 The University of London asserts copyright over all material in this subject guide except where otherwise indicated. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced in any form, or by any means, without permission in writing from the publisher. We make every effort to respect copyright. If you think we have inadvertently used your copyright material, please let us know. Contents Contents Introduction to the subject guide........................................................................... 1 Aims of the course.......................................................................................................... 1 Learning outcomes......................................................................................................... 1 Syllabus.......................................................................................................................... 2 Essential reading............................................................................................................ 2 Further reading............................................................................................................... 2 Online study resources.................................................................................................... 4 Subject guide structure and use...................................................................................... 5 Examination advice........................................................................................................ 6 Glossary of abbreviations used in this subject guide........................................................ 7 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects.................................................................................................................... 9 Aim of this chapter ........................................................................................................ 9 Learning objectives......................................................................................................... 9 Essential reading............................................................................................................ 9 Further reading............................................................................................................... 9 Overview........................................................................................................................ 9 Introduction................................................................................................................. 10 Fisher separation and optimal decision-making............................................................. 10 Fisher separation and project evaluation....................................................................... 13 The time value of money............................................................................................... 14 The net present value rule............................................................................................. 15 Other project appraisal techniques................................................................................ 17 Using present value techniques to value stocks and bonds............................................ 21 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 23 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 23 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 23 Chapter 2: Real options......................................................................................... 25 Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 25 Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 25 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 25 Further reading............................................................................................................. 25 Introduction................................................................................................................. 25 Decision tree, source of option value and early exercise................................................. 26 Three types of real options............................................................................................ 30 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 36 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 36 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 37 Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure............................................ 39 Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 39 Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 39 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 39 Further reading............................................................................................................. 39 Overview...................................................................................................................... 39 i FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Basic features of debt and equity.................................................................................. 40 The Modigliani–Miller theorem..................................................................................... 41 Modigliani–Miller and corporate taxation...................................................................... 43 Modigliani–Miller with corporate and personal taxation................................................ 46 Summary...................................................................................................................... 48 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 48 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 48 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 49 Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition.............. 51 Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 51 Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 51 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 51 Further reading............................................................................................................. 51 Overview...................................................................................................................... 51 Weighted average cost of capital.................................................................................. 52 Modigliani and Miller’s 2nd proposition........................................................................ 54 A CAPM perspective (optional)..................................................................................... 58 Summary...................................................................................................................... 59 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 60 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 60 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 61 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure............. 63 Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 63 Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 63 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 63 Further reading............................................................................................................. 63 Overview...................................................................................................................... 64 Capital structure, governance problems and agency costs.............................................. 64 Agency costs of outside equity and debt....................................................................... 64 Agency costs of free cash flows..................................................................................... 70 Firm value and asymmetric information......................................................................... 71 Summary...................................................................................................................... 75 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 76 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 76 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 76 Chapter 6: Equity financing................................................................................... 79 Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 79 Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 79 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 79 Further reading............................................................................................................. 79 Introduction................................................................................................................. 79 Private equity financing................................................................................................ 80 Initial public offerings and seasoned equity offerings..................................................... 85 IPO underpricing and winner’s curse............................................................................. 89 A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 92 Key terms..................................................................................................................... 92 Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 93 ii Contents Chapter 7: Dividend policy.................................................................................... 95 Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 95 Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 95 Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 95 Further reading............................................................................................................. 95 Overview...................................................................................................................... 96 How to return capital to equity holders?....................................................................... 96 Modigliani–Miller meets dividends................................................................................ 97 Prices, dividends and share repurchases........................................................................ 98 Dividend policy: stylised facts........................................................................................ 99 Taxation and clientele theory...................................................................................... 100 Asymmetric information and dividends........................................................................ 102 Agency costs and dividends........................................................................................ 103 Summary.................................................................................................................... 103 A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 104 Key terms................................................................................................................... 104 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 104 Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers...................................................................... 105 Aim of the chapter...................................................................................................... 105 Learning objectives..................................................................................................... 105 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 105 Further reading........................................................................................................... 105 Overview.................................................................................................................... 106 Merger motivations.................................................................................................... 106 Payment method in takeover....................................................................................... 107 The market for corporate control................................................................................. 110 The impossibility of efficient takeovers........................................................................ 110 Two ways to get efficient takeovers............................................................................. 112 Empirical evidence...................................................................................................... 113 Summary.................................................................................................................... 114 A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 115 Key terms................................................................................................................... 115 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 116 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging......................................................... 117 Aim of the chapter...................................................................................................... 117 Learning objectives..................................................................................................... 117 Essential reading........................................................................................................ 117 Further reading........................................................................................................... 117 Introduction............................................................................................................... 117 Why do firms hedge? ................................................................................................. 118 Typical financial instruments for hedging..................................................................... 123 Cost of risk management............................................................................................ 126 Interest rate parity and carry trade.............................................................................. 127 A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 129 Key terms................................................................................................................... 129 Sample examination questions.................................................................................... 130 iii FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes iv Introduction to the subject guide Introduction to the subject guide This subject guide provides you with an introduction to the modern theory of corporate finance. As such, it covers a broad range of topics and aims to give a general background to any student who wishes to do further academic or practical work in finance or accounting after graduation. We begin with project valuation methods and then examine issues that come under the broad heading of corporate finance. We will study how key decisions made by firms affect firm value and empirical evidence on these issues. The areas involved include: • the capital structure decision • dividend policy • mergers and acquisitions • raising equity • risk management. By studying these areas, you should gain an appreciation of: • optimal financial policy on a firm level • conditions under which an optimal policy actually exists • how the actual financial decisions of firms may be explained in theoretical terms. Aims of the course This course provides a theoretical framework used to address issues in project appraisal and financing, payout policy, capital structure, mergers and acquisitions, equity offerings and risk management. It provides students with the tools required for further studies in financial intermediation and investments. Learning outcomes At the end of this course, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain how to value projects, and use key capital budgeting techniques (for example: NPV and IRR) • understand and apply real option theory as an advanced technique of capital budgeting • understand and explain the relevance, facts and role of the payout policy, and calculate how payouts affect the valuation of securities • understand the trade-off firms face between tax advantages of debt and various costs of debt • calculate and apply different costs of capital in valuation • understand and explain different capital structure theories, including information asymmetry and agency conflict • understand how companies issue new shares, and calculate related price impact in security offerings 1 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance • discuss why merger and acquisition activities exist, and calculate the related gains and losses • understand risk, hedging, and numerous financial securities as tools to manage risk. Syllabus Students may bring into the examination hall their own hand-held electronic calculator. If calculators are used they must satisfy the requirements listed in the General Regulations. The up-to-date course syllabus for can be found in the course information sheet, which is available on the course virtual learning environment (VLE) page or on the LSE website: www.lse.ac.uk/study-at-lse/uolip/courseinformation-sheets Essential reading There are a number of excellent textbooks that cover this area. However, the following text has been chosen as the core text for this course due to its extensive treatment of many of the issues covered and up-to-date discussions: Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA, London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) 12th edition [ISBN 9781259253331]. At the start of each chapter of this guide, we will indicate the reading that you need to do from Brealey, Myers and Allen (2016). Detailed reading references in this subject guide refer to the editions of the set textbooks listed above. New editions of one or more of these textbooks may have been published by the time you study this course. You can use a more recent edition of any of the books; use the detailed chapter and section headings and the index to identify relevant readings. Also check the VLE regularly for updated guidance on readings. Further reading Please note that as long as you read the Essential reading you are then free to read around the subject area in any text, paper or online resource. You will need to support your learning by reading as widely as possible and by thinking about how these principles apply in the real world. To help you read extensively, you have free access to the VLE and University of London Online Library (see below). As further material, we will also direct you to the relevant chapters in two other texts. You may wish to look at the following two texts that are standard for many undergraduate finance courses: Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA: McGraw Hill, 2011) 2nd edition [ISBN 9780077129422]. Copeland, T., J. Weston and K. Shastri Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) 4th edition [ISBN 9780321223531]. A full list of all Further reading referred to in the subject guide is presented here for ease of reference. 2 Introduction to the subject guide Journal articles Allen, F. and R. Michaely ‘Dividend policy’ in Jarrow R.A., V. Maksimovic and W.T. Ziemba (eds) Handbooks in Operational Research and Management Science Volume 9 1995, pp.793–837. Asquith, P. and D. Mullins ‘The impact of initiating dividend payments on shareholders’ wealth’, Journal of Business 56(1) 1983, pp.77–96. Ball, R. and P. Brown ‘An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers’, Journal of Accounting Research 6(2) 1968, pp.159–78. Bhattacharya, S. ‘Imperfect information, dividend policy, and “the bird in the hand” fallacy’, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1) 1979, pp.259–70. Blume, M., J. Crockett and I. Friend ‘Stock ownership in the United States: characteristics and trends’, Survey of Current Business 54(11) 1974, pp.16–40. Bradley, M., A. Desai and E. Kim ‘Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms’, Journal of Financial Economics 21(1) 1988, pp.3–40. Grossman, S. and O. Hart ‘Takeover bids, the free-rider problem and the theory of the corporation’, Bell Journal of Economics 11(1) 1980, pp.42–64. Healy, P. and K. Palepu ‘Earnings information conveyed by dividend initiations and omissions’, Journal of Financial Economics 21(2) 1988, pp.149–76. Healy, P., K. Palepu and R. Ruback ‘Does corporate performance improve after mergers?’, Journal of Financial Economics 31(2) 1992, pp.135–76. Jarrell, G. and A. Poulsen ‘Returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: evidence from three decades’, Financial Management 18(3) 1989, pp.12–19. Jarrell, G., J. Brickley and J. Netter ‘The market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since 1980’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(1) 1988, pp.49–68. Jensen, M. ‘Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers’, American Economic Review 76(2) 1986, pp.323–29. Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976, pp.305–60. Jensen, M. and R. Ruback ‘The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence’, Journal of Financial Economics 11(1–4) 1983, pp.5–50. Lintner, J. ‘Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained earnings and taxes’ American Economic Review 46(2) 1956, pp.97–113. Masulis, R. ‘The impact of capital structure change on firm value: some estimates’, Journal of Finance 38(1) 1983, pp.107–26. Miles, J. and J. Ezzell ‘The weighed average cost of capital, perfect capital markets and project life: a clarification’, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (15) 1980, pp.719–30. Miller, M. ‘Debt and taxes’, Journal of Finance 32 1977, pp.261–75. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment’, American Economic Review (48)3 1958, pp. 261–97. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction’, American Economic Review (5)3 1963, pp. 433–43. Myers, S. ‘Determinants of corporate borrowing’, Journal of Financial Economics 5(2) 1977, pp.147–75. Myers, S. and N. Majluf ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.187–221. Poterba, J. and L. Summers ‘Mean reversion in stock prices: evidence and implications’, Journal of Financial Economics 22(1) 1988, pp.27–59. Ross, S. ‘The determination of financial structure: the incentive signalling approach’, Bell Journal of Economics 8(1) 1977, pp.23–40. Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny ‘Large shareholders and corporate control,’ Journal of Political Economy 94(3) 1986, pp.461–88. 3 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny ‘Managerial entrenchment: the case of managementspecific investment,’ Journal of Financial Economics 25 1989, pp.123–39. Travlos, N. ‘Corporate takeover bids, methods of payment, and bidding firms’ stock returns’, Journal of Finance 42(4) 1990, pp.943–63. Warner, J. ‘Bankruptcy costs: some evidence’, Journal of Finance 32(2) 1977, pp.337–47. Books Ravenscraft, D. and F. Scherer Mergers, selloffs, and economic efficiency. (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1987) [ISBN 9780815773481]. Online study resources In addition to the subject guide and the Essential reading, it is crucial that you take advantage of the study resources that are available online for this course, including the VLE and the Online Library. You can access the VLE, the Online Library and your University of London email account via the Student Portal at: https://my.london.ac.uk You should have received your login details for the Student Portal with your official offer, which was emailed to the address that you gave on your application form. You have probably already logged in to the Student Portal in order to register! As soon as you registered, you will automatically have been granted access to the VLE, Online Library and your fully functional University of London email account. If you have forgotten these login details, please click on the ‘Forgotten your password’ link on the login page. The VLE The VLE, which complements this subject guide, has been designed to enhance your learning experience, providing additional support and a sense of community. It forms an important part of your study experience with the University of London and you should access it regularly. The VLE provides a range of resources for EMFSS courses: 4 • Course materials: Subject guides and other course materials available for download. In some courses, the content of the subject guide is transferred into the VLE and additional resources and activities are integrated with the text. • Readings: Direct links, wherever possible, to essential readings in the Online Library, including journal articles and ebooks. • Video content: Including introductions to courses and topics within courses, interviews, lessons and debates. • Screencasts: Videos of PowerPoint presentations, animated podcasts and on-screen worked examples. • External material: Links out to carefully selected third-party resources • Self-test activities: Multiple-choice, numerical and algebraic quizzes to check your understanding. • Collaborative activities: Work with fellow students to build a body of knowledge. • Discussion forums: A space where you can share your thoughts and questions with fellow students. Many forums will be supported by Introduction to the subject guide a ‘course moderator’, a subject expert employed by LSE to facilitate the discussion and clarify difficult topics. • Past examination papers: We provide up to three years’ of past examinations alongside Examiners’ commentaries that provide guidance on how to approach the questions. • Study skills: Expert advice on getting started with your studies, preparing for examinations and developing your digital literacy skills. Note: Students registered for Laws courses also receive access to the dedicated Laws VLE. Some of these resources are available for certain courses only, but we are expanding our provision all the time and you should check the VLE regularly for updates. Making use of the Online Library The Online Library (http://onlinelibrary.london.ac.uk) contains a huge array of journal articles and other resources to help you read widely and extensively. To access the majority of resources via the Online Library you will either need to use your University of London Student Portal login details, or you will be required to register and use an Athens login. The easiest way to locate relevant content and journal articles in the Online Library is to use the Summon search engine. If you are having trouble finding an article listed in a reading list, try removing any punctuation from the title, such as single quotation marks, question marks and colons. For further advice, please use the online help pages (http://onlinelibrary. london.ac.uk/resources/summon) or contact the Online Library team: onlinelibrary@shl.london.ac.uk Subject guide structure and use You should note that, as indicated above, the study of the relevant chapter should be complemented by at least the Essential reading given at the chapter head. The content of the subject guide is as follows. • Chapter 1: here we focus on the evaluation of real investment projects using the net present value technique and provide a comparison of NPV with alternative forms of project evaluation. • Chapter 2: here we focus on what real options are and why they are important in project valuation. We discuss the source of option value and detail three types of real options: options to abandon, to expand and to wait. • Chapter 3: here we study a corporation’s capital structure. The essential issue is what levels of debt and equity finance should be chosen in order to maximise firm value. • Chapter 4: this chapter is complementary to Chapter 3, however rather than looking at values, as in Chapter 3, this chapter analyses discount rates. We learn that if there are no taxes, while the return on equity gets riskier as the level of debt increases, the average rate the firm pays to raise money is unchanged. In the presence of taxes, as debt increases, the average rate the firm pays to raise money decreases due to tax shields. 5 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance • Chapter 5: we look at more advanced issues in capital structure theory and focus on the use of capital structure to mitigate governance problems known as agency costs and how capital structure and financial decisions are affected by asymmetric information. • Chapter 6: here we analyse several different ways to issue new equity, some prominent features in equity offerings, and well-known frictions associated with equity issuance. The topics include staged financing in the private equity market, initial public offerings, seasoned equity offerings, rights offerings and the winner’s curse problem. • Chapter 7: here we examine dividend policy. What is the empirical evidence on the dividend pay-out behaviour of firms, and theoretically, how can we understand the empirical facts? • Chapter 8: we look at mergers and acquisitions, and ask what motivates firms to merge or acquire, what are the potential gains from this activity, and how can this be theoretically treated? We also explore how hostile acquisitions may serve as a discipline device to mitigate governance problems. • Chapter 9: this chapter answers why and how companies manage risks in their course of operation. We will discuss the reasons, typical financial instrument, and the associated costs of risk management. There is no specific chapter about corporate governance, but the agency related topics of Chapters 5 and 8 are inherently motivated by the existence of such problems. See also Grinblatt and Titman (2002) Chapter 18 for a broad overview on governance-related issues. Examination advice Important: the information and advice given here are based on the examination structure used at the time this guide was written. Please note that subject guides may be used for several years. Because of this we strongly advise you to always check both the current Regulations for relevant information about the examination, and the VLE where you should be advised of any forthcoming changes. You should also carefully check the rubric/ instructions on the paper you actually sit and follow those instructions. This course will be evaluated solely on the basis of a three-hour examination. Although the examiners will attempt to provide a fairly balanced coverage of the course, there is no guarantee that all of the topics covered in this guide will appear in the examination. Examination questions may contain both numerical and discursive elements. Finally, each question will carry equal weight in marking and, in allocating your examination time, you should pay attention to the breakdown of marks associated with the different parts of each question. Remember, it is important to check the VLE for: 6 • up-to-date information on examination and assessment arrangements for this course • where available, past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries for the course which give advice on how each question might best be answered. Introduction to the subject guide Glossary of abbreviations used in this subject guide ARR accounting rate of return CAPM capital asset pricing model IRR internal rate of return MM Modigliani–Miller NPV net present value 7 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes 8 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects Aim of this chapter The aim of this chapter is to introduce the Fisher separation theorem, which is the basis for using the net present value (NPV) for project evaluation purposes. With this aim in mind, we discuss the optimality of the NPV criterion and compare this criterion with alternative project evaluation criteria. Learning objectives At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • analyse optimal physical and financial investment in perfect capital markets and derive the Fisher separation result • justify the use of the NPV rules via Fisher separation • compute present and future values of cash-flow streams and appraise projects using the NPV rule • evaluate the NPV rule in relation to other commonly used evaluation criteria • value stocks and bonds via NPV. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 2 (Present Values), 3 (How to Calculate Present Values), 5 (The Value of Common Stocks), 6 (Why NPV Leads to Better Investment Decisions) and 7 (Making Investment Decisions with the NPV Rule). Further reading Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapters 1 and 2. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 9 (Discounting and Valuation), 10 (Investing in Risk-Free Projects), 11 (Investing in Risky Projects). Roll, R. ‘A critique of the asset pricing theory’s texts. Part 1: on past and potential testability of the theory’, Journal of Financial Economics 4(2) 1977, pp.129–76. Overview In this chapter we present the basics of the present value methodology for the valuation of investment projects. The chapter develops the NPV technique before presenting a comparison with the other project evaluation criteria that are common in practice. We will also discuss the optimality of NPV and give a number of extensive examples. 9 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Introduction What do firms do? They use resources to produce outputs. Often there are many different projects available, for example: • an engine manufacturer can choose to supply engines to Airbus or to Boeing • a school can offer different courses to students • and, similar to a firm, an individual can choose to supply labour to different companies. How do companies select projects? In this chapter, we answer this fundamental question. For the purposes of this chapter, we will consider a firm to be a package of investment projects. The key question, therefore, is how do the firm’s shareholders or managers decide on which investment projects to undertake and which to discard? Developing the tools that should be used for project evaluation is the emphasis of this chapter. It may seem, at this point, that our definition of the firm is rather limited. It is clear that, in only examining the investment operations of the firm, we are ignoring a number of potentially important firm characteristics. In particular, we have made no reference to the financial structure or decisions of the firm (i.e. its capital structure, borrowing or lending activities, or dividend policy). The first part of this chapter presents what is known as the Fisher separation theorem. What follows is a statement of the theorem. This theorem allows us to say the following: under certain conditions (which will be presented in the following section), the shareholders can delegate to the management the task of choosing which projects to undertake (i.e. determining the optimal package of investment projects), whereas they themselves determine the optimal financial decisions. Hence, the theory implies that the investment and financing choices can be completely disconnected from each other and justifies our limited definition of the firm for the time being. Fisher separation and optimal decision-making Consider the following scenario. A firm exists for two periods (imaginatively named period 0 and period 1). The firm has current funds of m and, without any investment, will receive no money in period 1. Investments can be of two forms. The firm can invest in a number of physical investment projects, each of which costs a certain amount of cash in period 0 and delivers a known return in period 1. The second type of investment is financial in nature and permits the firm to borrow or lend unlimited amounts at rate of interest r. Finally the firm is assumed to have a standard utility function in its period 0 and period 1 consumption. (By consumption we mean the use of any funds available to the firm net of any costs of investment.) Let us first examine the set of physical investments available. The firm will logically rank these investments in terms of their return, and this will yield a production opportunity frontier (POF) that looks as given in Figure 1.1. This curve represents one manner in which the firm can transform its current funds into future income, where c0 is period 0 consumption, and c1 is period 1 consumption. Using the assumed utility function for the firm, we can also plot an indifference map on the same diagram to find the optimal physical investment plan of a given firm. The optimal investment policies of two different firms are shown in Figure 1.1. 10 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects It is clear from Figure 1.1 that the specifics of the utility function of the firm will impact upon the firm’s physical investment policy. The implication of this is that the shareholders of a firm (i.e. those whose utility function matters in forming optimal investment policy) must dictate to the managers of the firm the point to which it invests. However, until now we have ignored the fact that the firm has an alternative method for investment (i.e. using the capital market). Figure 1.1 The financial investment allows firms to borrow or lend unlimited amounts at rate r. Assuming that the firm undertakes no physical investment, we can define the firm’s consumption opportunities quite easily. Assume the firm neither borrows nor lends. This implies that current consumption (c0) must be identically m, whereas period 1 consumption (c1) is zero. Alternatively, the firm could lend all of its funds. This leads to c0 being zero and c1 = (1 + r) m. The relationship between period 0 and period 1 consumption is therefore: c1 = (1 + r)(m – c0). (1.1) This implies that the curve which represents capital market investments is a straight line with slope –(1 + r). This curve is labeled CML on Figure 1.2. Again, we have on Figure 1.2 plotted the optimal financial investments for two different sets of preferences (assuming that no physical investment is undertaken). Figure 1.2 11 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Now we can proceed to analyse optimal decision-making when firms invest in both financial and physical assets. Assume that the firm is at the beginning of period 0 and trying to decide on its investment plan. It is clear that, to maximise firm value, the projects undertaken should be those with the greatest return. Knowing that the return on financial investment is always (1+r), the firm will first invest in all physical investment projects with returns greater than (1+r ). These are those projects on the production possibility frontier (PPF) between points m and I on Figure 1.3.1 Projects above I on the PPF have returns that are dominated by the return from financial investment. Hence, the firm physically invests up to point I. Note that, at this point, we have not mentioned the firm’s preferences over period 0 and period 1 consumption. Hence, the decision to physically invest to I will be taken by all firms regardless of the preferences of their owners. Preferences come into play when we consider what financial investments should be undertaken. The firm’s physical investment policy takes it to point I, from where it can borrow or lend on the capital market. Borrowing will move the firm to the south-east along a line starting at I and with slope –(1+r); lending will take the firm north-west along a similarly sloped line. Two possible optima are shown on Figure 1.3. The optimum at point X is that for a firm whose owners prefer period 1 consumption relative to period 0 consumption (and have hence lent on the capital market), whereas a firm locating at Y has borrowed, as its owners prefer date 0 to date 1 consumption. Figure 1.3 demonstrates the key insight of Fisher separation. All firms, regardless of preferences, will have the same optimal physical investment policy, investing to the point where the PPF and capital market line are tangent. Preferences then dictate the firm’s borrowing or lending policy and shift the optimum along the capital market line. The implication of this is that, as it is physical investment that alters firm value, all agents (i.e. regardless of preferences) agree on the physical investment policy that will maximise firm value. More specifically, the shareholders of the firm can delegate choice of investment policy to a manager whose preferences may differ from their own, while controlling financial investment policy in order to suit their preferences. Figure 1.3 12 1 The absolute value of the slope of the PPF can be equated with the return on physical investment. For all points below I on the PPF, this slope exceeds that of the capital market line and hence defines the set of desirable physical investment projects. Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects Fisher separation and project evaluation Fisher separation can also be used to justify a certain method of project appraisal. Figure 1.3 shows a suboptimal physical investment decision (I’) and the capital market line that borrowing and lending from point I’ would trace out. Clearly this capital market line always lies below that achieved through the optimal physical investment policy. Hence, one could say that optimal physical investment should maximise the horizontal intercept of the capital market line on which the firm ends up. Let us, then, assume a firm that decides to invest a dollar amount of I0. Given that the firm has date 0 income of m and no date 1 income, aside from that accruing from physical investment, the horizontal intercept of the capital market line upon which the firm has located is: where Π(I0) is the date 1 income from the firm’s physical investment. Maximising this is equivalent to the following maximisation problem: . The prior objective is the NPV rule for project appraisal. It says that an optimal physical investment policy maximises the difference between investment proceeds divided by one plus the interest rate and the investment cost. Here, the term ‘optimal’ is being defined as that which leads to maximisation of shareholder utility. We will discuss the NPV rule more fully (and for cases involving more than one time period) later in this chapter. The assumption of perfect capital markets is vital for our Fisher separation results to hold. We have assumed that borrowing and lending occur at the same rate and are unrestricted in amount and that there are no transaction costs associated with the use of the capital market. However, in practical situations, these conditions are unlikely to be met. A particular example is given in Figure 1.4. Here we have assumed that the rate at which borrowing occurs is greater than the rate of interest paid on lending (as the real world would dictate). Figure 1.3 shows that there are now two points at which the capital market lines and the production opportunities frontier are tangential. This then implies that agents with different preferences will choose differing physical investment decisions and, therefore, Fisher separation breaks down. Figure 1.4 13 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Agents with strong preferences for future consumption will physically invest to point X and then financially invest to an optimum on the capital market lending line (CML). Those with strong preferences for current consumption physically invest to point Y and borrow (along CML’). Finally, a set of agents may exist who value current and future consumption similarly, and these will optimise by locating directly on the PPF and not using the capital market at all. An example of an optimum of this type is point Z on Figure 1.4. The time value of money In the preceding section we demonstrated the Fisher separation theorem and the manner in which physical and financial investment decisions can be disconnected. The major implication of this theorem is that the set of desirable physical investment projects does not depend on the preferences of individuals. In the following sections we shall focus on the way in which individual physical investment projects should be evaluated. Our key methodology for this will be the NPV rule, mentioned in the preceding section. In the following sections we will show you how to apply the rule to situations involving more than one period and with time-varying cash flows. To begin, let us consider a straightforward question. Is $1 received today worth the same as $1 received in one year’s time? A naïve response to this question would assert that $1 is $1 regardless of when it is received, and hence the answer to the question would be yes. A more careful consideration of the question brings the opposite response however. Let’s assume I receive $1 now. If I also assume that there is a risk-free asset in which I can invest my dollar (e.g. a bank account), then in one year’s time I will receive $(1+r), assuming I invest. Here, r is the rate of return on the safe investment. Hence $1 received today is worth $(1+r) in one year. The answer to the question is therefore no. A dollar received today is worth more than a dollar received in one year or at any time in the future. The above argument characterises the time value of money. Funds are more valuable the earlier they are received. In the previous paragraph we illustrated this by calculating the future value of $1. We can similarly illustrate the time value of money by using present values. Assume I am to receive $1 in one year’s time and further assume that the borrowing and lending rate is r. How much is this dollar worth in today’s terms? To answer this second question, put yourself in the position of a bank. Knowing that someone is certain to receive $1 in one year, what is the maximum amount you would lend him or her now? If I, as a bank, were to lend someone money for one year, at the end of the year I would require repayment of the loan plus interest (at rate r). Hence if I loaned the individual $x, I would require a repayment of $x(1+r). This implies that the maximum amount I should be willing to lend is implicitly defined by the following equation: $x(1+r) = $1 (1.2) such that: (1.3) The value for x defined in equation 1.3 is the present value of $1 received in one year’s time. This quantity is also termed the discounted value of the $1. 14 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects You can see the present and future value concepts pictured in Figure 1.2. If you recall, Figure 1.2 just plots the CML for a given level of initial funds (m) assuming no funds are to be received in the future. The future value of this amount of money is simply the vertical intercept of the CML (i.e. m(1+r)), and obviously the present value of m(1+r) is just m. The present and future value concepts are straightforwardly extended to cover more than one period. Assume an annual compound interest rate of r. The present value of $100 to be received in k year’s time is: (1.4) whereas the future value of $100 received today and evaluated k years hence is: FVK (100) = 100(1 + r)K (1.5) Activity Below, there are a few applications of the present and future value concepts. You should attempt to verify that you can replicate the calculations. Assume a compound borrowing and lending rate of 10 per cent annually. a. The present value of $2,000 to be received in three years’ time is $1,502.63. b. The present value of $500 to be received in five years’ time is $310.46. c. The future value of $6,000 evaluated four years hence is $8,784.60. d. The future value of $250 evaluated 10 years hence is $648.44. The net present value rule In the previous section we demonstrated that the value of funds depends critically on the time those funds are received. If received immediately, cash is more valuable than if it is to be received in the future. The NPV rule was introduced in simple form in the section on Fisher separation. In its more general form, it uses the discounting techniques provided in the previous section in order to generate a method of evaluating investment projects. Consider a hypothetical physical investment project, which has an immediate cost of I. The project generates cash flows to the firm in each of the next k years, equal to Ck. In words, all that the NPV rule does is to compute the present value of all receipts or payments. This allows direct comparisons of monetary values, as all are evaluated at the same point in time. The NPV of the project is then just the sum of the present values of receipts, less the sum of the present values of the payments. Using the notation given above and again assuming a rate of return of r, the NPV can be written as: (1.6) Note that the cash flows to the project can be positive and negative, implying that the notation employed is flexible enough to embody both cash inflows and outflows after initiation. Once we have calculated the NPV, what should we do? Clearly, if the NPV is positive, it implies that the present value of receipts exceeds the present value of payments. Hence, the project generates revenues that outweigh its costs and should therefore be accepted. If the NPV is negative the project should be rejected, and if it is zero the firm will be indifferent between accepting and rejecting the project. 15 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance This gives a very straightforward method for project evaluation. Compute the NPV of the project (which is a simple calculation), and if it is greater than zero, the project is acceptable. Example Consider a manufacturing firm, which is contemplating the purchase of a new piece of plant. The rate of interest relevant to the firm is 10 per cent. The purchase price is £1,000. If purchased, the machine will last for three years and in each year generate extra revenue equivalent to £750. The resale value of the machine at the end of its lifetime is zero. The NPV of this project is: NPV = 750 + 750 + 750 – 1000 = 865.14. (1.1)3 (1.1)2 (1.1)1 As the NPV of the project exceeds zero, it should be accepted. In order to familiarise yourself with NPV calculations, attempt the following activities by calculating the NPV of each project and assessing its desirability. Activity Assume an interest rate of 5 per cent. Compute the NPV of each of the following projects, and state whether each project should be accepted or not. •• Project A has an immediate cost of $5,000, generates $1,000 for each of the next six years and zero thereafter. •• Project B costs £1,000 immediately, generates cash flows of £600 in year 1, £300 in year 2 and £300 in year 3. •• Project C costs ¥10,000 and generates ¥6,000 in year 1. Over the following years, the cash flows decline by ¥2,000 each year, until the cash flow reaches zero. •• Project D costs £1,500 immediately. In year 1 it generates £1,000. In year 2 there is a further cost of £2,000. In years 3, 4 and 5 the project generates revenues of £1,500 per annum. Up to this point we have just considered single projects in isolation, assuming that our funds were enough to cover the costs involved. What happens, first of all, if the members of a set of projects are mutually exclusive?2 The answer is simple. Pick the project that has the greatest NPV. Second, what should we do if we have limited funds? It may be the case that we are faced with a pool of projects, all of which have positive NPVs, but we only have access to an amount of money that is less than the total investment cost of the entire project pool. Here we can rely on another nice feature of the NPV technique. NPVs are additive across projects (i.e. the NPV of taking on projects A and B is identical to the NPV of A plus the NPV of B). The reason for this should be obvious from the manner in which NPVs are calculated. Hence, in this scenario, we should calculate all project combinations that are feasible (i.e. the total investment in these projects can be financed with our current funds). Then calculate the NPV of each combination by summing the NPVs of its constituents, and finally choose the combination that yields the greatest total NPV. Finally, we should devote some time to discussion of the ‘interest rate’ we have used to discount future cash flows. Until now we have just referred to r as the rate at which one can borrow or lend funds. A more precise definition of r is that r is the opportunity cost of capital. If we are considering the use of the NPV rule within the context of a firm, we have to recognise that the firm has several sources of capital, and the cost of each of these should be taken into account when evaluating the firm’s overall 16 By this we mean that taking on any one of the set of projects precludes us from accepting any of the others. 2 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects cost of capital. The firm can raise funds via equity issues and debt issues, and it is likely that the costs of these two types of funds will differ. Later on in this chapter and in those that follow, we will present techniques by which the firm can compute the overall cost of capital for its enterprise. Other project appraisal techniques The NPV methodology for project appraisal is by no means the only technique used by firms to decide on their physical investment policy. It is, however, the optimal technique for corporate management to use if they wish to maximise expected shareholder wealth. This result is obvious from our Fisher separation analysis. In this section we talk about three of NPV’s competitors, the payback rule, the internal rate of return (IRR) rule, and the multiples method, which are sometimes used in practice. The payback rule Payback is a particularly simple criterion for deciding on the desirability of an investment project. The firm chooses a fixed payback period, for example, three years. If a project generates enough cash in the first three years of its existence to repay the initial investment outlay, then it is desirable, and if it doesn’t generate enough cash to cover the outlay, it should be rejected. Take the cash-flow stream given in the following table as an example. Year Cash flow 0 1 2 3 4 –1,000 250 250 250 500 Table 1.1 A firm that has chosen a payback period of three years and is faced with the project shown in Table 1.1 will reject it as the cash flow in years 1 to 3 (750) doesn’t cover the initial outlay of 1,000. Note, however, that if the firm used a payback period of four years, the project would be acceptable, as the total cash flow to the project would be 1,250, which exceeds the outlay. Hence, it’s clear that the crucial choice by management is of the payback period. We can also use the preceding example to illustrate the weaknesses of payback. First, assume that the firm has a payback period of three years. Then, as previously mentioned, the project in Table 1.1 will not be accepted. However, assume also that, instead of being 500, the project cash flow in year 4 is 500,000. Clearly, one would want to revise one’s opinion on the desirability of the project, but the payback rule still says you should reject it. Payback is flawed, as a portion of the cash-flow stream (that realised after the payback period is up) is always ignored in project evaluation. The second weakness of payback should be obvious, given our earlier discussion of NPV. Payback ignores the time value of money. Sticking with the example in Table 1.1, assume a firm has a payback period of four years. Then the project as given should be accepted (as total cash flow of 1,250 exceeds investment outlay of 1,000). But what’s the NPV of this project? If we assume, for example, a required rate of return of 10 per cent, then the NPV can be shown to be negative. (In fact the NPV is –36.78. As a self-assessment activity, show that this is the case.) Hence application of the payback rule tells us to accept a project that would decrease expected shareholder wealth (as shown by application of the NPV rule). This flaw could be eliminated by discounting project cash flows that accrue within the payback period, giving a discounted payback rule, but such a modification still wouldn’t solve the first problem we highlighted. 17 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance The internal rate of return criterion The IRR rule can be viewed as a variant on the apparatus we used in the NPV formulation. The IRR of a project is the rate of return that solves the following equation: (1.7) where Ci is the project cash flow in year i, and I is the initial (i.e. year 0) investment outlay. Comparison of equation 1.7 with 1.6 shows that the project IRR is the discount rate that would set the project NPV to zero. Once the IRR has been calculated, the project is evaluated by comparing the IRR to a predetermined required rate of return known as a hurdle rate. If the IRR exceeds the hurdle rate, then the project is acceptable, and if the IRR is less than the hurdle rate it should be rejected. A graphical analysis of this is presented in Figure 1.5, which plots project NPV against the rate of return used in NPV calculation. If r* is the hurdle rate used in project evaluation, then the project represented by the curve on the figure is acceptable as the IRR exceeds r*. Clearly, if r* is also the correct required rate of return, which would be used in NPV calculations, then application of the IRR and NPV rules to assessment of the project in Figure 1.5 gives identical results (as at rate r* the NPV exceeds zero). Figure 1.5 Calculation of the IRR need not be straightforward. Rearranging equation 1.7 shows us that the IRR is a solution to a kth order polynomial in r. In general, the solution must be found by some iterative process, for example, a (progressively finer) grid search method. This also points to a first weakness of the IRR approach; as the solution to a polynomial, the IRR may not be unique. Several different rates of return might satisfy equation 1.7; in this case, which one should be used as the IRR? Figure 1.6 gives a graphical example of this case. 18 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects Figure 1.6 The graphical approach can also be used to illustrate another weakness of the IRR rule. Consider a firm that is faced with a choice between two mutually exclusive investment projects (A and B). The locus of NPV-rate of return pairings for each of these projects is given on Figure 1.7. The first thing to note from the figure is that the IRR of project A exceeds that of B. Also, both IRRs exceed the hurdle rate, r*. Hence, both projects are acceptable but, using the IRR rule, one would choose project A as its IRR is greatest. However, if we assume that the hurdle rate is the true opportunity cost of capital (which should be employed in an NPV calculation), then Figure 1.7 indicates that the NPV of project B exceeds that of project A. Hence, in the evaluation of mutually exclusive projects, use of the IRR rule may lead to choices that do not maximise expected shareholder wealth. Figure 1.7 19 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance The multiples method An alternative to using forecasts of a firm’s or project’s cash flows to calculate value, it is possible to use market information to estimate the value. The multiples method assesses the firm’s value based on the value of a comparable publically traded firm. For example, consider the firm’s market value to earnings ratio, this ratio tells us how much a dollar of earnings contributes to the present value according to the market’s consensus view. For publically traded firms, this ratio is available. The firm we wish to value may not have a publically available market value, however we are likely to know its earnings. If we assume that these two firms should have similar market value to earnings ratios, then we can value the firm by taking the publically available ratio and multiplying it by the firm’s earnings. Common multiples to use are market value to earnings, market value to EBITDA, market value to cash flow, and market value to book value. Some firms, especially younger firms, have no earnings or even negative earnings. In this case it may be better to value the firm as of some future date in which the firm’s cash flows have stabilised, and then to discount to today’s value. An alternative is to use more creative multiples, for example price to patent ratio, price to subscribers ratio, or price to Ph.D.’s ratio. It is often better to take an average over several comparable firms to calculate the multiple. If you believe the firm being valued is better or worse than the comparable firms, you can shade the multiple down or up, as in the example below. The multiples method is not an exact science but rather a convenient way to incorporate market beliefs. It should always be used in conjunction with another method, such as NPV. Example Below are the equity values, debt values, and earnings (in billions) for several large US retailers. Additionally provided is earnings growth for the past 10 years. Equity Debt E ∆E (10 yr) % JCP 17.48 3.81 1.10 7.8 COST 24.08 2.22 1.10 15.5 HD 82.08 12.39 6.01 21.2 WMT ? 47.44 11.88 15.7 TGT 50.14 14.14 2.58 19.2 Walmart’s (WMT’s) equity value is excluded as this is the quantity we wish to estimate. We can first calculate the market value of equity to earnings ratio for the average firm in the industry (excluding Walmart), this is: [(17.48/1.1) + (24.08/1.1) + (82.08/6.01) + (50.14/2.58)]/4 = 17.72 We now multiply this number by Walmart’s earnings to get Walmart’s equity value estimate: 17.72*11.88=210.49. Walmart’s actual equity value was $192.48 billion. In the example above we used multiples to value equity, we sometimes wish to the value of the full business (sometimes called enterprise value), in this case we would need to use the full business value (for example, debt plus equity) in the numerator instead of just equity value. Notice that the debt to equity ratio of Costco (COST) was 9.2 per cent while that of Target (TGT) was 28.2 per cent. In this example, we have ignored the effects of leverage (debt in the capital structure), however as we will see in a later chapter, leverage affects both firm value and the expected return on equity. Therefore, firms with different leverage ratios 20 Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects that look otherwise similar may have very different value to earnings ratios. We will learn how to adjust the multiples method for the effects of leverage later. The multiples method allows us to check whether the value of a conglomerate is equal to the sum of its parts. To estimate the value of each business division of a conglomerate we can calculate each division’s earnings and multiply it by the average value to earnings multiple of stand alone firms in the same sector. Adding up the value of all divisions gives us an estimated value for the conglomerate, this estimate is on average 12 per cent greater than the traded value of the conglomerate. This is called the conglomerate discount. The reasons for the conglomerate discount are not fully understood. It is possible that conglomerates are a less efficient form of organisation due to inefficient capital markets. It is also possible that the multiples method is inappropriate here because single segment firms are too different from divisions of a conglomerate operating in the same industry. The strength of the multiples approach is that it incorporates a lot of information in a simple way. It does not require assumptions on the discount rate and growth rate (as is necessary with the NPV approach) but just uses the consensus estimates from the market. A weakness is the assumption that the comparable companies are truly similar to the company one is trying to value; there is no simple way of incorporating company specific information. However, its strength is also its biggest weakness. By using market information, we are assuming that the market is always correct. This approach would lead to the biggest mistakes in times of biggest money making opportunities: when the market is overvalued or undervalued. The lesson of this section is therefore as follows. The most commonly used alternative project evaluation criteria to the NPV rule can lead to poor decisions being made under some circumstances. By contrast, NPV performs well under all circumstances and thus should be employed. Using present value techniques to value stocks and bonds To end this chapter, we will discuss very briefly how to value common stocks and bonds through the application of present value techniques. Stocks Consider holding a common equity share from a given corporation. To what does this equity share entitle the holder? Aside from issues such as voting rights, the share simply delivers a stream of future dividends to the holder. Assume that we are currently at time t, that the corporation is infinitely long-lived (such that the stream of dividends goes on forever) and that we denote the dividend to be paid at time t+i by Dt+i. Also assume that dividends are paid annually. Denoting the required annual rate of return on this equity share to be re, then a present value argument would dictate that the share price (P) should be defined by the following formula: . (1.8) Note that in the above representation we have assumed that there is no dividend paid at the current time (i.e. the summation does not start at zero). In plain terms, what equation 1.8 says is that an equity share is worth only the discounted stream of annual dividends that it delivers. 21 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance A simplification of the preceding formula is available when we assume that the dividend paid grows at constant percentage rate g per annum. Then, assuming that a dividend of D0 has just been paid, the future stream of dividends will be D0(1+g), D0(1+g)2, D0(1+g)3 and so on. This type of cash-flow stream is known as a perpetuity with growth, and its present value can be calculated very simply.3 In this setting the price of the equity share is: 0 3 See Appendix 1. (1.9) . This is the Gordon growth model of equity valuation. As is obvious from the preceding discussion, it is only valid if you can assert that dividends grow at a constant rate. Note also that if you have the share price, dividend just paid and an estimate of dividend growth, you can rearrange equation 1.9 to give the required rate of return on the stock – that is: . (1.10) The first term in 1.10 is the expected dividend yield on the stock, and the second is expected dividend growth. Hence, with empirical estimates of the previous two quantities, we can easily calculate the required rate of return on any equity share. Activity Attempt the following questions: 1. An investor is considering buying a certain equity share. The stock has just paid a dividend of £0.50, and both the investor and the market expect the future dividend to be precisely at this level forever. The required rate of return on similar equities is 8 per cent. What price should the investor be prepared to pay for a single equity share? 2. A stock has just paid a dividend of $0.25. Dividends are expected to grow at a constant annual rate of 5 per cent. The required rate of return on the share is 10 per cent. Calculate the price of the stock. 3. A single share of XYZ Corporation is priced at $25. Dividends are expected to grow at a rate of 8 per cent, and the dividend just paid was $0.50. What is the required rate of return on the stock? Bonds In principle, bonds are just as easy to value. • A discount or zero coupon bond is an instrument that promises to pay the bearer a given sum (known as the principal) at the end of the instrument’s lifetime. For example, a simple five-year discount bond might pay the bearer $1,000 after five years have elapsed. • Slightly more complex instruments are coupon bonds. These not only repay the principal at the end of the term but in the interim entitle the bearer to coupon payments that are a specified percentage of the principal. Assuming annual coupon payments, a three-year bond with principal of £100 and coupon rate of 8 per cent will give annual payments of £8, £8 and £108 in years 1, 2 and 3. In more general terms, assuming the coupon rate is c, the principal is P and the required annual rate of return on this type of bond is rb, the price of the bond can be written as:4 22 4 In our notation a coupon rate of 12 per cent, for example, implies that c = 0.12; the discount rate used here, rb , is called the yield to maturity of the bond. Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects . (1.11) Note that it is straightforward to value discount bonds in this framework by setting c to zero. Activity Using the previous formula, value a seven-year bond with principal $1,000, annual coupon rate of 5 per cent and required annual rate of return of 12 per cent. (Hint: the use of a set of annuity tables might help.) A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • analyse optimal physical and financial investment in perfect capital markets and derive the Fisher separation result • justify the use of the NPV rules via Fisher separation • compute present and future values of cash-flow streams and appraise projects using the NPV rule • evaluate the NPV rule in relation to other commonly used evaluation criteria • value stocks and bonds via NPV. Key terms capital market line (CML) consumption Fisher separation theorem Gordon growth model indifference curve internal rate of return (IRR) criterion investment policy net present value (NPV) rule payback rule production opportunity frontier (POF) production possibility frontier (PPF) time value of money utility function Sample examination questions 1. The Toyundai Motor Company has the opportunity to invest in new production line equipment, which would have a working lifetime of 10 years. The new equipment would generate the following increases in Toyundai’s net cash flows. In the first year of usage the new plant would decrease costs by $200,000. For the following six years the cost saving would fall at a rate of 5 per cent per annum. In the remaining years of the equipment’s lifetime, the annual cost saving would be $140,000. 23 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Assuming that the cost of the equipment is $1,000,000 and that Toyundai’s cost of capital is 10 per cent, calculate the NPV of the project. Should Toyundai take on the investment? 2. Describe two methods of project evaluation other than NPV. Discuss the weaknesses of these methods when compared to NPV. 3. The CEO and other top executives of a firm with no nearby commercial airports make approximately 300 flights per year with an average cost per flight of $5,000. The firm is considering buying a Gulfstream jet for $15 million. The jet will reduce the cost of travel to $300,000 (including fuel, maintenance, and other jet-related expenses). The firm expects to be able to resell the jet in five years for $12.5 million. The firm pays a 25 per cent corporate tax on its profits and can offset its corporate liabilities by using straight line depreciation on its fixed assets. The opportunity cost of capital is 4 per cent. a. Should the firm buy this jet if it has sufficient taxable profits in order to take advantage of all tax shields? b. Should the firm buy this jet if it does not have sufficient taxable profits in order to take advantage of new tax shields? c. Suppose the firm could lease an airplane for the first year, with an option to extend the lease. Within that year they would find out whether the local government has decided to build an airport nearby which would reduce travel costs. How would this change your calculations? 4. Suppose that you have a £10,000 student loan with a 5 per cent interest rate. You also have £1,000 in your zero interest checking account which you do not plan to use in the foreseeable future. You are considering three strategies: (i) pay off as much of the loan as possible, (ii) invest the money in a local bank at 3.5 per cent interest, (iii) invest in the stock market. The expected return on the stock market is 6 per cent for the foreseeable future. Your personal discount rate is 4 per cent for risk-free investments. For simplicity assume all investments are perpetuities. a. What is the NPV of strategy (i)? b. What is the NPV of strategy (ii)? c. What is the NPV of strategy (iii) if you are risk neutral? 24 Chapter 2: Real options Chapter 2: Real options Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to understand what real options are and how to quantify the option value. With this aim in mind, we study three types of real options (options to abandon, to expand and to wait) through several representative examples. Learning objectives At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain what real options are • explain why real options are important in project valuation • explain and calculate the source of option value • explain three types of real options: options to abandon, to expand, and to wait. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 10.4 (Real Options and Decision Trees) and 22 (Real Options). Further reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 20 (Understanding Options) and 21 (Valuing Options). Introduction In Chapter 1 we examined the use of present-value techniques in the evaluation of investment projects. A key assumption is that if managers decide to carry out a project, they never revise it subsequently. Clearly, this is not realistic. Managers may terminate the project early if things go wrong or may follow up with a new investment, if a trial is successful. Analogously, movie directors may decide to film a sequel of a movie if the original one performs well, but may decide not to if the first part performs poorly. In finance, we define real option as the right but not the obligation to modify the project in the future. Real options are valuable if the future is random, since they give us the flexibility to undertake projects only when it is beneficial to do so. This flexibility can be in the form of an opportunity to make more money or an opportunity to avoid losses. This ‘cherry-picking’ feature of real options is the main source of their value. Note that in case of deterministic future, the flexibility provided by real options, is meaningless. When there is no randomness, one can optimise all future actions (what, when or how much to invest) upfront and simply not deviate from this plan. Hence, there is no need for real options. In real life, however, the future is non-deterministic in most cases and real options are valuable. 25 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance In this chapter, we will consider decision trees – the key element to assess real options. We will explore the source of real option value and analyse whether it is optimal to exercise the option early. Then we will go over the three main types of real options: option to abandon, option to expand and option to wait. Decision tree, source of option value and early exercise Decision trees are simply a diagram of sequential decisions and possible outcomes. They are a key element to value real options and they illustrate the answers to three main questions: • What are the available actions? • When do you have them? • What is the payoff if an action is taken? Figure 2.1 shows a typical decision tree. The manager has the option to not test the project at the beginning or to stop the project in case of a failure. In both cases, the manager avoids a loss and the decision has 0 NPV instead of a negative one. Success Test Pursue project Invest $200,000 NPV=$2million Failure Manager has a choice Don’t test Stop project NPV=0 NPV=0 Figure 2.1: A typical decision tree. In the remainder of this section, we conduct a case study on a coffee shop project. Through this case, we will see a full-blown example of real options, the source of option value and when early exercise of the option is optimal. Example: Coffee shop case We consider building a coffee shop in London. The initial investment costs are £50,000 (in 2019). Cash flows will last for 10 years. Assume a risk-free rate of 2.1 per cent and a discount rate for the project of 10.5 per cent (timeline illustrated in Figure 2.2): Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 10 CF Year 0 Investment –50k Figure 2.2: Coffee shop benchmark timeline. The cash flows in years 1–10 are uncertain and there are two main sources of risk: market type risks and cash flow risks. The coffee market in London may be similar to either the one in Berkeley, CA, where the demand is generally stronger, or the one in Cleveland, OH, featuring weaker demand. 26 Chapter 2: Real options In addition to this market risk, the cash flow in each year can be high, medium or low in each market type. Table 2.1 summarises the probabilities of each market type and the cash flow outcomes. Type of market Probability of market type (Idiosyncratic) Demand Probability of demand type (Systematic) Annual cash flow (£ ‘000) Berkeley, CA 0.8 High 0.25 16 0.8 Med 0.50 11 0.8 Low 0.25 6 0.2 High 0.25 11 0.2 Med 0.50 6 0.2 Low 0.25 1 Cleveland, OH Table 2.1: Coffee-shop case risk analysis. Note that unlike the projections we had in Chapter 1, now the cash flow is random. This introduces uncertainty in the future and hence creates value for real options. But for the beginning, let us ignore the optionality and calculate the NPV for the benchmark case with no real options. First, let us find the NPV of the coffee shop project given each market type. Using the probabilities of each demand type from column 4, we can calculate the expected cash flows for years 1–10: E[Cash flow | Berkeley-type market ] = 0.25*6 + 0.50*11 + 0.25*16 = £11,000 E[ Cash flow | Cleveland-type market ] = 0.25*1 + 0.50*6 + 0.25*11 = £6,000 Then, the NPV of the project given each type is: 10 NPV Berkeley = − 50 + ∑ t=1 10 NPV = − 50 + Cleveland ∑ t=1 11 (1 + 0.105) t 6 (1 + 0.105) t = 16.2 = −13.9 Hence, the unconditional NPV at year 0 is: 0.8*NPVB + 0.2*NPVC = 0.8*16.2 + 0.2*(–13.9) = 10.1 The NPV is positive, so we should build the coffee shop. But can we do better? Yes, if we could hire a marketing research firm to learn the market type before investing, in Year –1. The new timeline is shown in Figure 2.3: Old Timeline Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 10 CF Year 0 Investment –50k Timeline with Market Research: Year -1 Market Research Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 10 CF Year 0 Investment –50k Figure 2.3: Coffee shop: time line with the market research. 27 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance If the research says that the market is Berkeley-type, we build the coffee shop as the NPV is positive. On the other hand, if the market is Cleveland, we withdraw as the NPV is negative. Thus, the new information creates real option – we have the right but not the obligation to build the coffee shop. The market research allows us to avoid losses in case of a Clevelandtype market. Figure 2.4 depicts the decision tree. Build Berkeley ~Build 0.8 0.2 Build Cleveland ~Build Figure 2.4: Coffee shop: decision tree with the market research. Let us now find out the value of the project with the market research. The NPV at year –1 is: NPV = 0.8 ∗ 16.2 + 0.2 ∗ 0 = 12.7 1 + 0.021 Now, instead of –13.9 (NPVC), we simply do not build the coffee shop and have a cash flow of 0 in the case of a Cleveland-type market. We discount at the risk-free rate, because from year –1 to year 0, we just hold cash (no risk). The project becomes more valuable with the real option: the NPV without research at year –1 is 10.1/1.021 = 9.9 < 12.7. How much are we ready to pay for the market research? We would be willing to pay up to the additional benefit that we obtain due to the research: 12.7 – 9.9 = £2.8,000. This is the first view of the source of option value: the difference between the NPV with and without the real option. An alternative view of the option value is to think of it as the marginal effect of change in action. How does the research change our investment decision? Without the option value, we cannot avoid losses in case of Cleveland-type market. However, with the option to withdraw from the project, we can avoid the negative NPV of building the shop. The NPV of savings evaluated at year –1 is 0.2*(0 – 13.9)/1.021 = £2.8,000. This is exactly the same as the previous figure! Until now, we have assumed that we can only start the project at year 0, even without research. In reality, however, market research takes time (say one year, in this example) and without research, the project starts immediately. The question is therefore, should we wait (start at year 0) or should we start immediately (at year –1) without research? Recall option theory: 28 • early exercise is never optimal for a US call option on a non-dividend paying stock • but early exercise may be optimal for a dividend paying stock. Chapter 2: Real options Let us see whether it is optimal to exercise our real option early. To emphasise the cost of waiting, suppose we only have the lease for the coffee shop for 10 years (year 0–9). If we do market research, we would lose one year’s cash flow (Figure 2.5). Year -1 Market Research Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 0 Investment -50K Year 1 CF Year 0 CF Year -1 Investment -50K Figure 2.5: Coffee shop: timeline with the market research and waiting. As our lease runs for 10 years, we give up one year of cash flow by waiting. Let us re-calculate the NPV with market research: 9 PV Berkeley PV = = − 50 + ∑ t=1 11 (1 + 0.105)t 0.8 * 12.1 + 0.2 * 0 1 + 0.021 = 12.1 = 9.48 < 10.1 The £4.1,000 = (16.2 – 12.1) drop in value is analogous to a dividend payment for a stock. It is the cost of sacrificing one year of cash flows. We miss out on the dividend by not exercising early. Analogously to a US option on a dividend-paying stock, in this case it is optimal to exercise before maturity. In other words, the foregone benefit (one-year cash flow) is greater than the loss we avoid (taking a negative NPV project if a Cleveland-type market) and it is optimal to build the shop immediately (exercise early) rather than to wait for the outcome of the market research (delay exercise). To sum up, real options are valuable because they give us the flexibility to avoid bad projects. However, waiting can be costly if valuable production opportunities are sacrificed. This is similar to losing dividend when delaying the exercise of a stock option. Activities 1. Which of the following examples are applications of real options: I) An investment in the IT business II) The valuation of an option to purchase additional handset units for resale III) The option to develop a new drug IV) The decision to abandon a test facility Select one: a. I, II, III and IV b. I, II, and III only c. I only d. I and II only 29 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance 2. You are thinking about an investment opportunity. To implement the opportunity, you need to invest $5 million (C0). The investment will produce Q = 30,000 units of products every year. The price of the product P is $40 per unit and the unit cost is $25. Your discount rate is 6 per cent per year. Calculate the NPV if you invest today. Select one: a. +7.5 million b. + 4 million c. None of the above d. +2.5 million 3. Following the same setup as in Question 2 but the only difference is that the price of the product is random. Suppose the unit price P is either $60 or $30 next year with equal probability, then expected NPV of the project if postponed by one year is: Select one: a. +5 million b. +5.9 million c. None of the above d. –2.5 million Three types of real options In this section, we study three types of real options commonly observed in practice – option to abandon, option to expand, and option to wait. The option to abandon gives us the flexibility to withdraw from the project in case it is no longer profitable. This option is used to disengage from failing deals. The option to expand gives us the right to expand an existing project. This option is beneficial if, for example, investment turns out to be more profitable than expected. In that case, it is valuable to be able to put more money on it. The option to wait is beneficial if we have a positive NPV project, which, if implemented in the future, may have an even higher NPV. It is valuable if we have the option to delay investment. Let us consider each of these three options in more detail. Option to abandon There are two main subcategories of this option: temporary abandonment and permanent abandonment. To understand the temporary abandonment option, consider the following example. Example: Gold mine We have the rights to operate a gold mine for three years, starting now. The mine produces 50,000 ounces of gold per year. The costs of extraction are $230/ounce and the current price of gold is $220/ounce. The discount rate is 5 per cent. The price of gold in each period has two equally likely outcomes: it either rises by 20 per cent, or falls by 10 per cent (shown in Figure 2.6). 30 Chapter 2: Real options 317 264 220 0.5 0.5 0.5 238 0.5 238 198 0.5 0.5 178 Figure 2.6: Gold mine – gold price dynamics. Let us first calculate the plain NPV without any real options. First, let us find the expected price of gold in the first and the second period: E0 [P1Gold] = 0.5*264 + 0.5*198 = 231 E0 [P2Gold] = 0.25*317 + 0.5 * 238 + 0.25*178 = 242.75 Then, the NPV is: NVGold mine = 50(220 − 230) + 50 (231−230) 1.05 + 50 ( 242.75 − 230) 1 .05 2 = 126 The cash flows are calculated as the price of gold less the cost multiplied with the amount produced. 4350 1700 −500 0.5 = (317 − 230)(50) 0.5 0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50) 0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50) −2600 = (178 − 230)(50) −1600 0.5 0.5 Figure 2.7: Gold mine cash flows. As we see, we make a loss from the mine if the gold price drops in the first period and also if it drops in the second period. Can we avoid these losses? Yes, if we have the option to temporarily stop extraction. Suppose we can temporarily abandon production (close down the mine) if the gold price is too low. Let us recalculate the cash flows by inserting zeros at nodes where the profit is negative, and recalculate the NPV. 31 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance 4350 1700 0 = (317 − 230)(50) 0.5 0.5 0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50) 0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50) 0.5 0.5 0 0 Figure 2.8: Gold mine cash flows with abandonment option. With 0.5*0.5 = 0.25 probability, the price continues to rise and the cash flow is 1,700 in the first period, 4,350 in the second period. Analogously, with 0.25 probability, the price goes ‘up and down’ and the cash flow is 1,700 in the first period, 400 in the second period. Using the same logic for ‘down and up’ and ‘down and down’, the final NPV is: + 0.25 0 + 4350 (1 + 0.05)2 [ 1 + 0.05 + 400 (1 + 0.05)2 [ 1700 400 + 0.25 1 + 0.05 + (1 + 0.05)2 [ [ [ 1700 = 1978 > 126 With the abandonment option, the project is much more valuable because we can avoid the losses in case the price of gold is low. What is the source of the option value? Just like in the coffee shop example, there are two ways to calculate it. We can get it either as the difference between the two NPVs (1978 – 126 = 1852), or, alternatively, as the NPV of the negative cash flows that is saved by the abandonment option, which also gives 1,852. Now let us consider permanent abandonment. Consider the following example. Suppose we have set up our own company. Now we receive a nonretractable offer from an outside investor, to buy our company for $150 million at or before year 1. The company’s cash flow projection is illustrated in Figure 2.9. The discount rate is 10 per cent. The questions we need to answer are: 1. what is the value of the offer? 2. when should we abandon the company for good? Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 120(.6) 100 (.6) 90(.4) 0 70(.6) 50 (.4) 40(.4) Figure 2.9: Projected cash flow (year 1 and 2) of the company. 32 [ NVGold mine = 0 + 0.25 + Chapter 2: Real options To answer these questions, let us calculate the NPV at all nodes. At node 100, the NPV is: 100 + [120(0.6) + 90(0.4)] / 1.1 = 198 > 150. The NPV is greater than the value of the offer, so we do not sell. At node 50, the NPV is: 50 + [70(0.6) + 40(0.4)] / 1.1 = 102.72 < 150. The NPV is less than the value of the offer, so we sell. At year 0, the NPV is: [198(0.6)+102.72(0.4)] / 1.1 = 145.4 < 150. Do you want to sell? No! Why? Let us think carefully. Note that unlike the temporary abandonment, the key in permanent abandonment is to decide when the project should be abandoned. We use backward induction: given the optimal abandonment decision at day 1, what’s the day 0 NPV? Drawing a new decision tree illustrates the situation. Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 120(.6) 100 (.6) 90(.4) 0 150 (.4) Figure 2.10: Permanent abandonment – backward induction. The new NPV is: NPV0 = [198(0.6) + 150(0.4)]/1.1 = 162. We do not want to sell at year 0 since 162>150. The option value can be calculated again either as the difference between the two NPVs (162 – 145 = 17) or as the present value of the marginal changes: we can dump the firm at 150 million when the continuation cash flows are worth only 102.72 million. The latter occurs with 0.4 probability and the PV of the gain is (150 – 102.72)*0.4/1.1 = 17. This again gives the same option value. Option to expand As outlined at the beginning of this section, this option gives us the right to expand an existing project if it turns out to be profitable. In that case, we would be willing to invest more money in it. Example: Executive flying business You are thinking about starting an executive flying business. The first-year demand will be high with probability 60 per cent and low with probability 40 per cent. If the first-year demand was high, subsequent-year demand will be also high with probability 80 per cent and low with probability 20 per cent. On the other hand, if the first-year demand was low, subsequentyear demand will be high with probability 40 per cent and low with probability of 60 per cent. The risk-free rate is 10 per cent. One option is 33 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance to purchase a Turboprop plane for $550,000 that will generate the following cash flows (see Figure 2.11). 960 (.8) +150(.6) 220(.2) -550 930(.4) +30(.4) 140(.6) Figure 2.11: Executive flying business – Turboprop plane. Let us find the NPV of the Turboprop plane: NPV = − 550 + .6(150) + .4 (30) 1.10 + .6[.8(960) + .2(220)] + .4[.4(930) + .6(140)] 1.102 = 96.12 The project is positive NPV. But can we do better? Suppose we have another option: purchase a Piston-engine (smaller) plane for $250,000 today and another for $150,000 if demand is high. The latter has an implicit option to expand if demand is high. The cash flows are depicted in Figure 2.12. 800(.8) +100(.6) { -150 or 100(.2) 410(.8) 0 -250 180(.2) 220(.4) +50(.4) 100(.6) Figure 2.12: Executive flying business – Piston engine. First, let us find out whether we should buy a second plane when demand is high. The upper node on Figure 2.12 shows the cash flows if we purchase the second plane: .8 * 800 + .2 * 100 1.1 − 150 = 450. This is greater than the cash flow without buying it: 450 > .8 * 410 + .2 * 180 1.1 so we decide to expand by purchasing a second Piston-engine plane. Then the NPV of the resulting Piston-engine strategy is: NPV = − 250 + .6(−50) + .4(50) 1.10 + .6[.8(800) + .2(100) + .4[.4(220) + .6(100)] 1.102 As we see from this example, staged implementation is usually better: NPVPISTON = $117,000, NPVTURBO = $96,000. What is the source of option value? Suppose we ignore the option to expand, then NPVPISTON/NE = $52,000. Hence, we can calculate the value of the option to expand as the difference between the two NPVs, analogously to before: 117,000 – 52,000 = $65,000. Alternatively, we can calculate it again as the present value of the marginal changes. The option value comes from the ability to invest $150,000 for a 34 = 117.11 Chapter 2: Real options second Piston plane and get incremental cash flow of 800 – 410 = 390 with probability 0.8, and of 100 –180= –80 with probability 0.2. This opportunity exists with probability 0.6. Hence, the present value of this investment is [(390*0.8 – 80*0.2)/1.1 – 150]*0.6/1.1 = $65,000. This is again the same as the previous option value. Option to wait As outlined at the beginning, this option gives us the flexibility to delay investment. Even when the project currently has a positive NPV, it may be more valuable if we wait for a better timing. Recall the stock option: you can exercise now and pocket profits (if any) or you have the option to exercise later, hoping for even larger profit. We can decompose the option value into intrinsic value and time premium: option value = intrinsic value + time premium. The intrinsic value is the profit if you exercise now. For example, for a call option, it is max(Stock Price – Strike Price,0). The time premium is the value of being able to wait (shown in Figure 2.13). The black curve is the intrinsic value, and the gap between the dotted and black curves is the value of the option to wait (the time premium). Essentially, the time premium is the additional benefit of the stock option that gives us the flexibility to exercise with larger profits in the future. Option Price Intrinsic Value Option value Time Premium Stock Price Figure 2.13: Intrinsic value and time premium of an option. An important idea in the option to wait is the optimal timing of exercising the option. For example, it might be optimal to exercise a US option on a dividend-paying stock before maturity, if the additional benefit from the dividend exceeds the benefit from being able to wait. The same logic applies to real options. Even projects with positive NPV may be more valuable if deferred. The actual NPV is then the current value of some future value of the deferred project: Net future value as of date t Current NPV = (1 + r)t Consider the following example. Example: Tree harvest Suppose we may harvest a set of trees at any time over the next five years. The net future values are shown in the table below. Assume a 10 per cent discount rate. Given the future values of delaying the harvest, which harvest date maximises the current NPV? Harvest year 0 1 2 3 4 5 Net FV ($1000s) 50 64.4 77.5 89.4 100 109.4 28.8 20.3 15.4 11.9 9.4 % change in value Table 2.2: Tree harvest: future values. 35 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Let us calculate the current NPVs for years 0–5: 64.4 NPV if harvested in year 1= = 58.5 1.10 Analogously, we get the NPVs if harvested in years 0–5 (shown in Table 2.3): Harvest year 0 1 2 3 4 5 NPV ($1000s) 50 58.5 64.0 67.2 68.3 67.9 Table 2.3: Tree harvest: NPVs. Hence, it is optimal to harvest in year 4 (highest NPV). Activities 4. Are the following statements true or false? a. The option to expand increases NPV b. High abandonment value decreases NPV c. If a project has positive NPV, the firm should always invest immediately 5. An abandonment option, in effect (select one): a. Limits the flexibility of management’s decision-making. b. Applies only to new projects. c. Limits the profit potential of a proposed project. d. Limits the downside risk of an investment project. A reminder of your learning outcomes At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain what real options are • explain why real options are important in project valuation • explain and calculate the source of option value • explain three types of real options: options to abandon, to expand, and to wait. Key terms Decision tree Early exercise Option to abandon Option to expand Option to wait Option value 36 Chapter 2: Real options Sample examination questions 1. You are deciding between two technologies for production of a Marley Richards’ motorcycle: Technology A uses state-of-the-art customdesigned techniques to produce the complex shapes required for the motorcycles in high volumes and at low cost. But if the motorcycle does not sell, the equipment will be worthless. Technology B uses standard machine tools. Labour costs are much higher, but the machinery can be sold for $100 million if the motorcycle does not sell. Payoffs from Producing Outboard ($ millions) Technology A Technology B Buoyant demand 185 180 Sluggish demand 85 80 Assume that the present value of the project is $115 million at year 0 if Technology A is used. What is the present value in year 0 if Technology B is used, ignoring the abandonment value? The risk free rate is 7 per cent. 2. The R&D division at your company has just synthesised new lowtemperature resistant material. You decide to go ahead and produce this material commercially as there is high demand for such materials in the space industry. It will take five years to find out whether the material is commercially viable, and you estimate that the risk neutral probability of success is 25 per cent. Development will cost $100 million per year, paid at the beginning of each year. If development is successful and you decide to produce the material, the factory will be built immediately. It will cost $10 billion to put in place, and will generate risk-free profits of $1 billion at the end of every year in perpetuity. The five-year risk-free interest rate today is 10 per cent per year, and the yield on a perpetual risk-free bond will be 5 per cent, 8 per cent, 10 per cent or 12 per cent in five years. The risk-neutral probability of each rate is 25 per cent. What is the value today of this project? 37 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes 38 Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to analyse and explain the choices of corporate capital structures made by firms’ managers. With this aim in mind, we first introduce a stylised model in which capital structure is irrelevant (Modigliani–Miller). We then relax some of the assumptions made in this stylised model in order to explain empirical evidence on firms’ capital structures. Learning objectives By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • outline the main features of risky debt and equity • derive and discuss the Modigliani–Miller theorem • analyse the impact of taxes on the Modigliani–Miller propositions. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapter 19 (How Much Should a Firm Borrow?). Further reading Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapter 15. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 14 (How Taxes Affect Financing Choices) and 16 (Bankruptcy Costs and Debt Holder-Equity Holder Conflicts). Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment’, American Economic Review (48)3 1958, pp.261–97. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction’, American Economic Review (5)3 1963, pp.433–43. Warner, J. ‘Bankruptcy costs: some evidence’, Journal of Finance 32(2) 1977, pp.337–47. Overview In the preceding chapters of this guide we studied capital budget – the choice of investment projects assuming the firm has required capital to implement these projects. In particular, we have considered how a manager should evaluate projects given projected future cash flows and possible future actions that the manager may take. Thus far, however, we have said nothing about how the firm can raise the required investment capital, typically the mix of securities actually issued by corporations. Should firms aim to use a large proportion of debt in their financing or, conversely, should they employ equity financing in the main? In this chapter and the next we examine the firm’s decision over which types of claim to issue. The most important result we will find is that, under a certain set of assumptions, the firm is indifferent about the 39 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance mix of debt and equity that it uses in its financing. This result is the first Modigliani–Miller theorem (MM1). We go on to explore deviations from the MM1 assumptions and how this affects the debt–equity choice through the introduction of taxation effects, costly bankruptcy and information asymmetries. Basic features of debt and equity Before moving into our analysis it is useful to introduce the most basic securities actually issued by corporations: risky debt and equity. Corporations hold debt in many forms. They borrow money from banks through straightforward loan and overdraft facilities, they issue corporate debt, and they have trade credit with their trading partners. The bonds issued by firms can have complicated features, such as convertibility, the ability to be called and differences in seniority. To simplify matters, however, we will think of corporate debt as being composed of a number of bonds. Each bond entitles the holder to claim a fixed amount of cash from the firm at a given maturity date. The amount reclaimed is termed the face value of the debt. Two important features of corporate debt are as follows. 1. In times of corporate bankruptcy (the cash flow to the firm being less than the claims upon it), bond-holders have priority over equityholders (i.e. they get their share of the cash first). 2. Interest paid to debt claims is deductible from a corporation’s corporate tax bill. The latter point will not be used at present but will come in later. The first of the preceding pair of points implies that corporate debt has the following payoff function. Payoff [Xt , B] – B 0 B Xt Figure 3.1: Debt holders payoff. The horizontal axis of the graph above represents the cash flow to the firm (X), and the vertical axis shows the payoff to debt assuming the amount promised to the group of all debt-holders (the face value) is denoted B. When the cash flow to the firm is less than the face value, the debt-holders gain the entire amount. For values of the cash flow at and above the face value, the payoff to debt-holders is constant at B. 40 Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure The holders of corporate equity receive the residual cash flow accruing to the firm after payments to debt-holders. However, despite having a claim that is junior to that of debt-holders, equity-holders elect the board of a firm and have voting rights over corporate activities and are hence the true owners of the corporation. Equity also comes in many forms, but we will focus on the characteristics of common stock.1 Stock-holders receive cash income in the form of dividend payments. These payments, unlike payments to service debt, are not deductible from corporation tax obligations. Given the residual nature of the equity claim, the payoff to equity is as given in Figure 3.2. 1 Other types of equity include preferred stock and warrants. Payoff [Xt – B, 0]+ 0 B Xt Figure 3.2: Equity holders payoff. When the firm’s cash flow (X) is at or less than the face value of debt (B), equity-holders receive nothing. However, they receive every dollar of cash flow greater than B. This gives the kinked payoff function shown in Figure 6.2, which (anticipating future developments) is of precisely the same form as that of a European call option. The Modigliani–Miller theorem We now know what corporate debt and equity claims look like. One unanswered question, however, is what mix of debt versus equity should firms issue? In finance parlance, the ratio of the market value of debt to that of equity is known as the leverage or gearing ratio. Hence, the preceding question can be rephrased as follows. What is the optimal leverage ratio that a firm should aim for? This question was addressed in the 1950s by Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller. They showed the result that is the focus of the current section: under given assumptions, firms are indifferent about their leverage. This is because firms with differing debtto-equity ratios but the same investment policies have identical values, and hence there is no value to leverage. The assumptions underlying MM1 are as follows: • capital markets have no frictions (including no taxes or transactions costs) • investors have perfect information and homogeneous expectations • investors care only about their wealth • financing decisions do not affect investment outcomes. 41 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance To prove their indifference proposition, Modigliani and Miller used the notion of absence of arbitrage, meaning that the two different assets that generate the exact same payoffs in the future must share the same price today. Consider two firms. The first is entirely equity-financed, and we call it firm U. A second firm has an identical set of investment projects but has issued both debt and equity. We shall refer to the second firm as firm L and assume it has issued B units of debt that earn interest at rate rd. Finally, assume for simplicity’s sake that everything in our world lasts for one period only. Consider an investor who holds a proportion α of firm U’s equity. As this firm is solely equity-financed, our individual always earns a proportion α of firm U’s cash flow (X). Assume that the same agent also buys α of firm L’s equity and α of firm L’s debt. When the cash flow to firm L is less than the face value of its debt (B) obligations, our investor earns α of the cash flows through his share of total debt. When cash flow exceeds the face value of debt, he also gets a payoff on his equity claim. In Table 3.1 we show the payoff to our investors’ positions in both firms under two scenarios. The first represents the case where the cash flows to the two firms are smaller than the face value of firm L’s debt. The second case is when firm U’s cash flows exceed firm L’s debt obligations. Note that, in both cases, the investor earns an identical amount from their two positions, regardless of the actual cash-flow outcome. Hence, in line with the absence of arbitrage argument, the two positions must be identically priced. Type of claim Debt Payoff from position in U X < B(1 + rd) X > B(1 + rd) 0 0 Payoff from position in L X < B(1 + rd) X > B(1 + rd) αX αB(1 + rd) Equity αX αX 0 α(X–B(1 + rd)) Total αX αX αX αX Table 3.1 The price of the position in the unlevered firm is just αVU where the value of the unlevered firm is denoted VU. The value of the position in the levered firm is αE + αD = α(E+D), where E is the market value of the levered firm’s equity, and D is the market value of the levered firm’s debt. Of course, the total value of the levered firm (VL) must be the sum of E and D. Hence, the price of the levered position is αVL. Equating the price of levered and unlevered position yields the result that VU = VL, which is the MM capital structure irrelevance proposition. The key to the above result is that financing decisions do not affect investment outcomes. Hence, two firms with identical investment policies will derive identical returns regardless of their financing. As their investment proceeds are the same, they should have the same value.2 Another key point is that none of their cash flow goes to anyone outside those who own debt and equity. An alternative way to show the MM capital structure irrelevance proposition is to show that stakeholders in the firm are indifferent to changes in the firm’s capital structure. The reason for this is that stakeholders can, without cost, undo any changes the firm makes through their own trading in the firm’s securities. Consider once more an investor who owns a proportion α of firm L’s equity. The payoff associated with this position is α(X – B(1+rd)). Firm 42 2 You can think of this result in the following way: when you slice a cake, you do not reduce the size of the cake you sliced. Debt and equity are just different slices of firm cash flow and, based on the preceding logic, the value of the firm (size of the cake) is independent of the leverage ratio (way in which you slice the cake). Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure L now chooses to repurchase half of its equity (costing E/2) and funds the repurchase with the issue of new debt. Hence, the face value of debt outstanding becomes B1 = B + E/2. Assuming that none of our investor’s equity was repurchased, their payoff would be 2α(X – B1(1 + rd)) after the repurchase. This is obviously different to that prior to the capital structure change. However, our investor can restore their original payoff profile using the following strategy. Sell one-half of their equity stake and use the proceeds to buy debt. The payoff from the new position is α(X – B1(1 + rd)) + α(1 + rd)E/2 = α(X – B(1 + rd)). Hence our investor can, without cost, undo any change the firm makes in its capital structure. This implies that investors will be indifferent to such changes, and hence the valuation of a firm will not depend on the specific debt–equity ratio it chooses (i.e. the MM irrelevance proposition is valid). Example Consider an entrepreneur with a project which requires an initial investment of $100m and which will have perpetual cash flows of $20m forever or $5m forever with equal probability. Assume that all investors are risk neutral and require a 10 per cent expected rate of return. We can show that the entrepreneur is indifferent between raising $100m with debt, equity, or a mix of debt and equity. •• Debt: the entrepreneur must promise investors a coupon such that in expectations they receive interest of 100*.1 = $10m every year. Since in the bad state of the world investors will receive no more than $5m, it must be the case that .5*c + .5*5 = 10 and c = 15. The entrepreneur will receive the remainder: 0 in the bad state of the world and 20 – 15 = 5 in the good state of the world. In expectation, the present value of this is .5*5/.1 = $25m. •• Equity: the entrepreneur must promise investors a fraction α of future equity payouts. In expectation, outside equity investors will receive α*(.5*5 + .5*20) = 12.5α each year. The present value of this is 12.5α/.1 = 125α. This must equal to the amount they put in: 100 = 125α and α = 80 per cent. The entrepreneur receives the remainder of the equity, (1 – α)*12.5 = $2.5m every year. The present value of this is $25m. •• Mix: the entrepreneur raises $50m through debt. They must promise investors a coupon such that in expectations they receive interest of 50*.1 = $5m every year. Since even in the bad state of the world the firm can pay $5m, they promise them a coupon of $5m. The total equity payout is the remainder: 0 in the bad state of the world and 20 – 5 = $15m in the good state of the world; this is equal to .5*15 = $7.5m in expectation. The entrepreneur promises equity investors a fraction α of future equity payouts. In expectation outside equity investors will receive 7.5α, per year, or 7.5α/.1 = 75α in present value. This must equal to the $50m they have contributed, resulting in α = 66.7 per cent. The entrepreneur is left with (1 – α)*75 = $25m. The entrepreneur is indifferent to the choice of capital structure because capital structure does not affect total cash flows produced by the firm. Modigliani–Miller and corporate taxation One of the assumptions underlying MM’s irrelevance proposition is that there are no frictions in capital markets. One very pertinent and realistic friction is taxation, however. Firms are taxed on their profits and investors on their income from dividends, capital gains and interest income. Incorporating taxation into our analysis will result in the irrelevance of capital structure breaking down. The reason underlying this problem is that dividend and interest payments are not treated symmetrically in the 43 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance calculation of a firm’s corporation tax bill, and similarly investors are taxed differentially on their income from interest and from capital gains. Hence, the choice of firm capital structure will affect the after-tax stream of payments to all stakeholders and hence change the value of the firm. To start, consider a world in which investors are not taxed at all on their personal incomes. However, firm profits are taxed. Interest payments to debt, however, are made prior to the calculation of the corporation tax bill, whereas dividend payments must be paid out of after-tax income. As suggested above, the fact that debt service payments are made out of pre-tax cash flow and payments to equity out of post-tax cash flow will cause the breakdown of the irrelevance proposition. Debt is now a more favourable security to issue than equity. To illustrate, consider an infinitely lived, levered firm. Assume that the firm earns net cash flow Xt in period t, and that interest of rdB must be paid every period. Finally, assume that the probability of defaulting on the debt is always zero.3 In period t, the following funds are paid to investors in the firm: Ct = rd B + (1 – τc )(Xt – rdB) = (1 – τc) Xt + τcrd B, (3.1) where τc is the corporation tax rate. The first term on the right-hand side of equation 3.1 is precisely the payment made by an unlevered firm with cash flow Xt in period t. The second term is the gain made by the levered firm in saving on its corporation tax bill through using debt in the capital structure. This is known as the tax shield advantage of debt finance. As our firm is infinitely lived, its market value is calculated as the present value of the perpetual stream of payments to investors. Discounting and adding up the stream of payments represented by the first term on the right-hand side of equation 3.1 gives us the value of an unlevered firm (VU), with identical cash flows to our levered firm. Discounting the stream of payments represented by the second term on the right-hand side of equation 3.1 gives τcD, where D is the market value of debt. Hence the value of the levered firm can be written as: VU = VL + τcD. (3.2) The value of a firm increases linearly with the market value of its debt and, as such, firms should aim to have as high a leverage as possible. Note that, when the corporation tax rate is zero, the MM proposition is satisfied once more. In the following section, we show how firm valuation is affected by the introduction of personal taxes on investor income as well as taxes on corporate profits. Example Consider the same entrepreneur as in the previous example but now living in a world where corporate taxes are 15 per cent. We can show that the entrepreneur wishes to raise as much money as possible through debt. •• Debt: the coupon payment offered to creditors is c = $15m, exactly as before. The entrepreneur will receive the remainder, but must pay taxes on it. This is 0 in the bad state of the world and (20 – 15)*(1 – .15) = 4.25 in the good state of the world. In expectation the present value of this is .5*4.25/.1 = $21.25m. 44 •• Equity: the entrepreneur must promise investors a fraction α of future equity payouts. In expectation, outside equity investors will receive α*(.5*5 + .5*20) (1 – .85) = 10.625α each year. The present value of this is 10.625α/.1=106.25α. This must equal to the amount they put in: 100 = 106.25α and α = 94.12%. The entrepreneur receives the remainder of the equity, (1 – α)*10.625 = $.625m every year. The present value of this is $6.25m. 3 For this to hold we must have Xt > rd B in every period t. Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure •• Mix: the coupon payment offered to creditors is $5m, exactly as above. The total equity payout is the remainder: 0 in the bad state of the world and (20 – 5)* (1 – .15) = $12.75m in the good state of the world; this is equal to .5*12.75 = $6.375m in expectation. The entrepreneur promises equity investors a fraction α of future equity payouts. In expectation outside equity investors will receive 6.375 α, per year, or 6.375α/.1 = 63.75α in present value. This must equal to the $50m they have contributed, resulting in α = 78.43%. The entrepreneur is left with (1 – α)*63.75 = $13.75m. The entrepreneur is best off raising money with 100 per cent debt, next best off with a 50/50 mix, and worst off raising money with 100 per cent equity. As noted above, the addition of corporation tax to the MM analysis implies that firms should choose leverage ratios as large as possible. However, this is a clearly counterfactual implication. It has been suggested that relaxing another of MM’s assumptions can reconcile the facts with our analysis. The assumption that we relax is that bankruptcy is a cost-less process for firms to undergo.4 MM assume that, if a firm’s cash flow is insufficient to cover debt service (bankruptcy), then all funds are transferred immediately and without cost to bond-holders. However, in reality bankruptcy involves direct costs, such as lawyers’ fees, and indirect costs, such as debt-holder– equity-holder conflicts in financially distressed firms. For empirical evidence on the costs of bankruptcy in US railroad firms, see Warner (1977). 4 Figure 3.3: Optimal leverage under trade-off theory. As a result, we once more modify our analysis to allow for the effects of bankruptcy costs. We assume that firms with higher levels of debt in their capital structure incur greater costs of financial distress and that, at very high debt levels, the effect of such costs may outweigh tax shield effects.5 You will find a diagrammatic analysis of this situation in Figure 3.3, which plots firm value against leverage under three different scenarios. The first is when corporation tax and bankruptcy costs are both zero. Scenario 2 introduces non-zero corporation tax, and the third scenario allows for non-zero costs of bankruptcy. High debt levels imply large fixed nominal payments every period and hence expose the firm to financial distress if cash flows are unexpectedly low. 5 Figure 3.3 makes the point quite well. When debt levels become too large, the costs of financial distress outweigh tax shield gains and imply a finite optimal leverage ratio. This is in contrast to the case when bankruptcy is costless as firm value then increases without bound as leverage rises. Example Consider the same entrepreneur as in the previous example who still faces a 15 per cent corporate tax, but now also a drop of 40 per cent in all future income in case of bankruptcy. We can show that the entrepreneur wishes to raise money through a mix of 45 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance debt and equity because using all equity results in losses of tax shields while too much debt results in paying bankruptcy costs. •• Debt: the entrepreneur must promise investors a coupon such that in expectations they receive interest of 100*.1 = $10m every year. In the bad state of the world the firm is unable to fully pay its creditors and the firm will default. At this point, the creditors will take over the firm, but 20 per cent is lost to bankruptcy costs so their annual payout is 5*(1 – .4) = 3. It must be the case that .5*c + .5*3 = 10 and c = 17. The entrepreneur will receive the remainder, after taxes. This is 0 in the bad state of the world and (20 – 17)*(1 – .15) = 2.55 in the good state of the world. In expectation the present value of this is .5*2.55/.1 = $12.75m. •• Equity: the firm cannot be bankrupt since it carries no debt, therefore the solution is identical to the previous example. The entrepreneur receives $6.25m. •• Mix: note that in the previous example the coupon payment was just low enough for the firm to not default (in the bad state of the world equity is left with zero but creditors are fully paid, this is not default). Since no bankruptcy costs are paid, the solution is identical to the previous example. The entrepreneur receives $13.75m The entrepreneur is best off raising money by a mix of debt and equity so that they can take advantage of the tax benefits of debt without having leverage so high as to suffer bankruptcy costs. The idea that firm value is maximised by some intermediate leverage which balances out the tax benefit of debt and the costs of financial distress is called trade-off theory. However trade-off theory is out of favour because empirically the costs of bankruptcy appear to be too low to observe the low amounts of debt firms typically have in their capital structure. The average leverage ratio for large US firms is 1/3. Estimates of direct costs have been estimated as 7.5 per cent of market value for small firms by Ang (1982) but only 2.9 per cent for firms listed on AMEX and NYSE by Weiss (1990). Indirect costs are likely to be somewhat larger, but are harder to estimate. Modigliani–Miller with corporate and personal taxation Before closing this chapter, we briefly examine how personal taxation affects the Modigliani–Miller analysis when introduced in conjunction with corporate taxation. For the analysis in this section, we revert to the assumption that bankruptcy costs are zero. Consider a world with the following tax structure. Corporate profits are taxed at τc. Personal income, including that obtained from corporate interest payments, is taxed at rate τd. Finally, personal income from holdings of equity is taxed at rate τe. Assume that firms are infinitely lived, and consider a firm that pays rD B of its gross income at any point as interest. As interest payments are tax-deductible, the amount of interest that reaches the firm’s bond-holders’ bank accounts is: rDB(1 – τd). (3.3) In period t, the firm pays out an amount Xt – rD B to equity-holders. This amount is taxed twice: first at the corporate level and second at the personal level. Hence, the net amount that reaches equity-holders’ pockets is: (Xt – rD B)(1 – τc)(1 – τe). (3.4) Hence, in total, in period t, the firm pays out the following amount: Ct = (Xt – rD B) (1 – τc)(1 – τe) + rDB(1 – τd). 46 (3.5) Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure This expression can be rearranged to yield the following: Ct = Xt (1 –τc)(1 – τe) + rD B[(1 – τd) – (1 – τe)(1 – τc)]. (3.6) Note that the first term in equation 3.6 is precisely the cash-flow stream accruing to equity-holders in an unlevered firm (with identical cash flows to the levered firm). Hence, discounting this stream of funds at the appropriate rate yields a present value of VU. The second term is the extra money paid out, as the firm has debt in its capital structure. This should be discounted at the after-tax rate of return on debt (i.e. (1 – τd)rD). The sum of the present values of these two terms is clearly the value of the levered firm. Hence we can write: (3.7) This generalises equation 3.2 to the personal (as well as corporate) taxation case. Note that equation 3.2 can be retrieved as a special case of equation 3.7, when both personal tax rates are set to zero. The second term on the right-hand side of 3.7 is the taxation gain of debt. It is increasing in the corporate tax rate and the tax rate on equity income and decreasing in the tax rate on debt income. Note that, if (1 – τc)(1 – τe) > (1 – τd), then the tax advantage is negative, such that the optimal capital structure choice is to be all equity. If the preceding inequality is reversed, though, the tax advantage is clearly positive and, as such, optimal capital structure involves a firm issuing as much debt as possible. The Miller equilibrium Let us consider again the Modigliani–Miller setting with corporate and personal taxes. The Miller equilibrium is derived in such a setting when investors differ in their tax rates on personal income. The Miller equilibrium is obtained by stating that demand for debt must be equal to supply for debt in equilibrium. Let us denote respectively the (expected) rates of return offered by debt and equity, gross of personal taxes, but after adjusting for risk premiums, by rD and rE. In this new setting, firms are willing to issue debt exclusively as long as, after adjusting for risk premiums, the cost of debt after corporate taxes is strictly lower than the cost of equity, that is, as long as: rD (1 – τc) < rE. (3.8) Investors are willing to hold debt as long as, after adjusting for risk premiums, the return after personal income taxes offered by debt is weakly higher than the return after personal taxes on equity income offered by equity, that is, as long as: rD (1 – τd) ≥ rE (1 – τe). (3.9) In order to understand the Miller equilibrium, let us first assume that the pre-tax return on debt, rD, offered by firms is equal to the pre-tax return on equity, rE. In this case, firms are willing to issue debt which tax-exempt investors are willing to buy as both inequalities (equations 3.8 and 3.9) are satisfied. Firms have an incentive to increase leverage and will continue to replace equity with debt, moving up the demand curve by increasing the return rD they offer to attract investors with higher personal income tax rates, until: rD = [rE(1 –τe)]/(1 – τd) = rE /(1 – τc). (3.10) If the rate of return offered on debt is lower than rE /(1 – τc), firms have still incentives to issue more debt as, at this point, it is still profitable to issue 47 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance debt to investors with marginally higher personal income tax rates. In contrast, if the rate of return offered on debt is higher than rE/(1 – τc), firms would be better off issuing equity than debt as it is cheaper. In equilibrium, there is thus no advantage for firms to issue debt as the equilibrium rate of return offered to debt-holders is such that firms are indifferent between issuing debt and equity. In equation 3.7, the value of the levered firm, VL, is equal to the value of the unlevered firm, VU, as: (1 – τc) (1 – τe) = 1 – τd. (3.11) The after-tax Miller’s theory hence implies that there is an equilibrium aggregate amount of debt outstanding in the economy which is determined by relative corporate and personal tax rates. The amount of debt issued by any particular firm is, however, a matter of indifference. Summary In this chapter we have presented a fundamental analysis of the capital structure of a firm. Initially we show that, under the MM assumptions, capital structure does not affect firm value. We then present relaxations of the MM assumptions and demonstrate how the MM result is altered. With the introduction of corporate taxation it becomes clear that firm value is increasing with the level of debt in the capital structure. Also allowing for costly bankruptcy, we find that an optimal, finite capital structure may result. When personal taxes and corporate taxes are included, then the prescriptions for optimal capital structure are unclear. The optimum depends on the particular constellation of corporate and personal taxation rates. In the next chapter we will explore the same relationships but from the perspective of returns rather than values. In the following chapter we will examine how conflicts between debt and equity-holder interests will also imply that the MM result is violated. The analysis presented focuses on simple cases in which the choices of equity-holders (those who dictate the firm’s investment policy) are not aligned with the interests of debt-holders. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • outline the main features of risky debt and equity • derive and discuss the Modigliani–Miller theorem • analyse the impact of taxes on the Modigliani–Miller propositions. Key terms bankruptcy costs capital structure corporate taxes leverage Miller equilibrium Modigliani–Miller irrelevance theorem personal taxes tax shield of debt 48 Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure Sample examination questions 1. What assumptions underlie Modigliani and Miller’s proposition that firm value should be independent of capital structure? 2. Using a simple two-period model of an unlevered firm and a levered firm with B units of riskless debt outstanding, demonstrate the Modigliani–Miller proposition. In the same framework, show that an investor is indifferent to the firm altering its capital structure. 3. Demonstrate the impact of corporate and personal taxation on the relationship between firm value and capital structure using a simple infinite horizon framework. What would be the optimal capital structure for firms if the only form of taxation was corporate? 4. A start-up firm needs $100 million to launch its product. It has already signed a contract to provide its services to one major customer, this will result in $5 million in profits annually in perpetuity, starting this year. There is a 50 per cent chance the firm will sign a contract with a second customer with expected profits of $15 million in annual profits. If this deal is not signed, the firm only has $5 million in profits. The corporate tax is 15 per cent. In case of bankruptcy, 40 per cent of firm value is lost. Everyone is risk neutral with a 10 per cent discount rate. a. Suppose the start-up funds the $100 million through equity. What share of equity must be offered to outside investors? What is the present value of the initial investors’ stake. b. Suppose the start-up funds the $100 million through debt (perpetuity). What coupon payment must be offered to creditors? What is the present value of the initial investors’ stake. c. Suppose the start-up funds half of the $100 million through debt and the rest through equity. What coupon payment must be offered to creditors? What share of equity must be offered to outside investors? What is the present value of the initial investors’ stake. What is the best way to finance this project? Comment on trade-off theory. d. Suppose there were no bankruptcy costs. What would be the optimal choice of financing? 5. Firm A pays ¥15 million in the good state and ¥10 million in the bad state. It is an all equity firm and you own 10 per cent of the equity. Assume there are no taxes. The price per share is ¥10 with one million shares outstanding. a. What is your payout in the good state and in the bad state? b. The other owners have decided to recapitalise the firm. They raise ¥6 million by selling riskless bonds with a face value ¥7 million. They use this money to repurchase equity at the market price. You did not sell any of your shares. How much equity did they repurchase? What share of equity do you now on? What is your payout in the good state and in the bad state? c. Compare the expected return on your investment before and after the transaction. Why did the expected return change? d. You are risk averse and do not like the change to your return profile. Describe what you can do to get your payoff to be just the same as before the transaction. Comment on what the Modigliani– Miller 1st proposition in relation to this question. 49 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes 50 Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to derive relationships between the rate of return on a firm’s equity, the rate of return on a firm’s debt, and the rate of return on the firm’s total assets (WACC). We will derive the Modigliani and Miller 2nd proposition to analyse these relationships in the presence of corporate taxes. Learning objectives By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • write down the relationship between debt, equity, the unlevered return on the firm, and the levered return on the firm • understand what happens to equity returns, and the weighted average cost of capital as leverage increases with and without taxes • draw a link between Modigliani–Miller’s 1st and 2nd propositions • find the equity beta of a firm by unlevering and relevering the equity beta of a comparable firm with different capital structure. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 18 (Does Debt Policy Matter?) and 20 (Financing and Valuation). Further reading Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 13 (Corporate Taxes and the Impact of Financing on Real Asset Valuation), 14 (How Taxes Affect Financing Choices) and 15 (How Taxes Affect Dividends and Share Repurchases). Miles, J. and J. Ezzell ‘The weighed average cost of capital, perfect capital markets and project life: a clarification’, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (15) 1980, pp.719–30. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment’, American Economic Review (48)3 1958, pp.261–97. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction’, American Economic Review (5)3 1963, pp.433–43. Overview In Chapter 1 we learned how to calculate the value of a project by computing the present value of the project’s future cash flows. This was done by discounting the cash flows by the appropriate discount rate. In this chapter we will see how this discount rate changes as the capital structure of the firm changes. We will see that as the firm increases its leverage, its equity becomes more risky. The required rate of return on equity therefore increases. However the overall return on the firm’s assets (WACC) does not change if there are 51 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance no corporate taxes. This is analogous to results from the previous chapter: Modigliani–Miller’s 1st proposition stated that the firm’s value did not change with leverage when there were no corporate taxes. We will see that because taxes result in a safe cash flow returned to the firm in the form of a reduced tax liability, in the presence of corporate taxes the expected return on the firm’s assets decreases with leverage as the assets become safer due to increased tax shields. This is also analogous to results from the previous chapter: as the firm increases leverage, its value increases in the presence of corporate taxes. Weighted average cost of capital In this section, we first derive the weighted average cost of capital in a world without corporate tax. Then we introduce tax and study how it affects the cost of capital. Let’s first consider a world without corporate tax. A firm with total asset V is financed by both equity E and debt (or bond) B, and hence: V = E + B. (4.1) The equity and debt holders require returns of re and rd respectively. When the capital market is competitive, these returns are also the expected returns to the respective security holders. From the firm’s perspective, resources that must be paid to the equity and debt investors in order to generate these returns are the cost of financing the productive asset. Therefore, the expected returns to equity and debt are also known as the cost of equity and cost of debt. Our firm is currently financed by a mixture of debt and equity, so we naturally want to know its average financing cost, which is also the discount rate we shall use to calculate the present value of all future cash flows generated by the productive assets. The total resource that must be paid to equity and debt investors is: reE + rdB. (4.2) which must be generated from operating the asset. Therefore, to make the production worthwhile, the asset must deliver a minimum return of: ( B +E E r + ( B +E E r = ( V e ( (reE + rdB) d (4.3) This is the rate of return which should discount the total cash flow coming from the firm (that is, the cash flows to debt and equity) in order to calculate the total value of the firm (that is, the value of debt plus equity). Expression (4.3) is known as the weighted average cost of capital (WACC). From the expression, it is clear that WACC is the average cost of equity and cost of debt weighed by their respective composition in the total asset value. Now we introduce corporate income tax. If interest payment to the debt holders is tax deductible, then the cost of borrowing through debt becomes cheaper, as it lowers the tax bill of the company. Hence, the average cost of capital should therefore lower. Consider a firm with pre-tax annual cash flows Xt. Its value today is V0 and its value next year, after X1 has been paid out, is V1. If this firm has outstanding debt with market value B0, then its equity is valued E0=V0– B0. Suppose that the appropriate returns on debt and equity are rd and re respectively. Recall from the previous chapter that if this firm has perpetual outstanding debt with face value B then rdB will be distributed to the creditors in the 52 Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition form of a dividend, and the rest (Xt – rdB)(1 – τC) will be distributed to equity holders after corporate taxes. Define the free cash flow (FCF) as the after-tax cash flow available to be distributed by a similar but all equity firm. In this case, the firm’s FCF each year is Xt(1 – τC). Let us calculate the discount rate r, which would make the discounted present value of the FCF equal to V0, the combined value of the debt and equity. By definition of a return: V0 = [Xt(1 – τc) + V1]/(1 + r). (4.4) which can be rewritten as: r = (Xt(1 – τc) + V1 – V0)/V0. (4.5) We wish to solve for the r in equation 4.5 as a function of the return on debt, return on equity, and the tax rate. Note that the expected increase in value between years 0 and 1 is: (Xt – rdB0) (1 – τc) + rdB0+ V1 – V0 = [X1(1 – τc) + V1 – V0] + τcrdB0 (4.6) where the first term is the payment to equity holders, the second term is the payment to creditors, and the third term is the value of all assets remaining in the firm. The formulation on the right of 4.6 merely rearranges terms on the left hand side. Note that this increase in expected value must be split between the return to equity holders and the return to debt holders: [X1(1 – τc) + V1 – V0]+ τcrdB0 = E0 rd + B0re. (4.7) [X1(1 – τc) + V1 – V0]/V0 = (E0 rd + (1 – τc)B0re)/V0. Finally, substitute equation 4.5 for the left hand side, and note that V0 = E0 + B0 to find the WACC: 0 0 0 ( ( E E+ B re + (1 – τC) ( E B+ B 0 0 0 ( WACC = r = rd (4.8) Thus, the WACC is the discount rate at which the FCF needs to be discounted in order to calculate the firm’s value. The FCF is the cash flow to a hypothetical all equity firm, while the WACC accounts for the firm’s leverage. When corporate taxes are zero, equation 4.8 collapses to 4.3, however in the presence of taxes, WACC decreases as leverage increases. The intuition is similar to the Modigliani–Miller 1st proposition. For every extra dollar of debt in its capital structure, the firm receives τcrd back as a tax refund. This tax refund is a riskless payment, therefore the firm appears less risky and the average rate of return it pays to raise money decreases. Because of the refund, effectively, the firm is paying (1 – τc)rd instead of rd to raise money through debt. Example Walmart has an expected equity return of re = 8.5%. Walmart has AA debt which matures in 2023 and has a yield of 5.9%. Walmart’s tax rate is 35% so Walmart is paying (1 – τc )rd =(1 – 0.35) * 5.9 = 3.835% to raise money through debt. Walmart’s outstanding debt has a value of $22.7 billion. Walmart has 4,269 million shares outstanding with a price of $55.69 per share, implying an equity market capitalization of 4.269 * 55.69 = $237.7 billion. Walmart’s weight of debt in the capital structure is 22.7/(237.7 + 22.7) = 8.7% and its weight of equity is 237.7/(237.7 + 22.7) = 91.3%. Walmart’s WACC is 0.087 * 3.835 + .913 * 8.5 = 8.09%. 53 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Modigliani and Miller’s 2nd proposition In the previous section we derived the relationship between the return on the firm’s debt, the return on its equity, and the average cost of capital for that firm. In this section we will make a distinction between the firm’s unlevered (or asset return), which is the return this firm would pay to raise capital if it was an all equity firm, and the firm’s actual cost of capital, once we account for leverage, this is the WACC from the previous section. We will also find a relationship between the firm’s equity return and its unlevered return. In the absence of taxes, the MM 2nd proposition states that: re = ru + (B/E)(ru – rd ), (4.9) where B/E is the debt to equity ratio in the firm’s capital structure, re is the return on the firm’s equity, rd is the return on the firm’s debt, and ru is the unlevered return, or the return on a hypothetical firm that is financed by all equity (or unlevered) but otherwise similar to the firm we are considering. As leverage increases, the expected return on equity grows because equity becomes riskier. Equity is riskier because it is a residual payment, it is paid last after all other claims (such as debt) have been settled. When leverage is high, equity is only a small portion of the firm, but must take the brunt of most of the firm’s losses. This makes the equity of a highly levered firm very risky. Let us illustrate this fact by a simple example which shows how higher leverage can boost earnings per share, increase volatility and expected return to equity. Example. Miller’s Firm Professor Miller has an unlevered firm (no debt). The firm information is summarised in Table 4.1: Number of shares 1,000 Price per share ($) 10 Market value of shares ($) 10,000 Outcomes A B C D Operating income ($) 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 Earnings per share 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 Return on shares (%) 5 10 15 20 Table 4.1: Professor Miller’s firm without leverage. Column C is the average outcome, i.e. average earnings per share (EPS) are 1.5 and average return on shares is 15 per cent. Now, assume Professor Miller raises the leverage to 50 per cent debt at 10 per cent interest: Data 54 Number of shares 500 Price per share ($) 10 Market value of shares ($) 5,000 Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition Outcomes A B C D Operating income ($) 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 Interest ($) 500 500 500 500 Equity earnings ($) 0 500 1,000 1,500 Earnings per share ($) 0 1 2 3 Return on shares (%) 0 10 20 30 Table 4.2: Professor Miller’s firm with leverage. Looking at column C of Table 4.2, which is the expected outcome, we can see that higher leverage increases average EPS and return on shares: the average EPS are 2, and the average return on shares is 20 per cent. However, it also increases the variance of returns, thus making returns also more risky. Figure 4.1 illustrates the result from Tables 4.1 and 4.2 graphically. The dashed line shows the EPS as a function of operating income for Table 4.1 and the black line for Table 4.1. For the same range on the x-axis (say, 500 to 1,500), the black graph gives a wider set of values on the y-axis (0 to 2.5) compared to the dotted one (0.5 to 1.5). This is evidence of higher variance (risk): Earnings per share (EPS), dollars 3.00 2.50 2.00 Equal proportions debt and equity Expected EPS with debt and equity Expected EPS with all equity 1.50 All equity 1.00 Expected operating income 0.50 0.00 500 1000 1500 2000 Operating income, dollars Figure 4.1: Effect of leverage on EPS. Changing leverage does change the return, but not the firm value. It also does not change the WACC Notice that equation 4.9 is identical to equation 4.3 if we substitute WACC for ru and rearrange terms. When there are no taxes (or other frictions), as leverage increases, the equity return becomes riskier and its expectation grows to compensate investors for that risk. However, the average return that the firm pays to borrow does not change. This is because although equity returns grow, equity is a smaller part of the firm and carries less weight. Thus the firm is borrowing more through debt, which has a lower rate of return. The weighted average does not change. In the absence of corporate taxes, 55 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance the average rate at which the firm raises money, the WACC, is equal to the rate at which an all equity (or unlevered) firm raises money, ru. The WACC is independent of capital structure, analogous to the MM 1st proposition in the absence of taxes. The relationship between equity, debt, WACC and leverage in the absence of taxes is illustrated graphically in Figure 4.1. r rE rA = WACC rD D E Figure 4.2: Weighted average cost of capital without tax. We will now derive a more general version of the MM 2nd proposition, in the presence of taxes. Consider a firm that lives for one period. It has both debt and equity in its capital structure and its value is V0 = E0 + B0 today and V1 = E1 + B1 next period. Also note that from the definition of return, E1 = (1 + re)E0 and B1 = (1 + rd)B0 as there are no intermediate payments. This firm will have a cash flow X1 which it will distribute to its debt and equity holders in period 1. Also consider a similar firm that is all equity owned. This unlevered firm has value V0U today; for this firm B = 0. Since next period the cash flows will be distributed first to creditors, and then to equity-holders (after taxes), we can write the value of the firm as the value of the total distributions: V1 = (X1 – B1)(1 – τC) + B1 = X1 (1 – τC) + τCB1 = V1U + τC B1, (4.10) where the first term is the payout to equity-holders and the second term is the payout to creditors. The last equality uses the fact that the value of the unlevered firm next period is just equal to its after-tax cash flows. From the definitions of debt and equity we know that: V1 = E1 + B1 = (1 + re)E0 + (1 + rd)B0. (4.11) Setting equations 7.10 and 7.11 equal to each other and substituting V1U = (1 + ru)V0U and B1 = (1 + rd)B0 we get the following equation: (1 + ru)V0U + τC (1 + rd)B0 = (1 + re)E0 + (1 + rd)B0. (4.12) Now, we can rearrange the terms of this to solve for the return on equity: 1 + re = (1 + ru)(V0U/E0) – (1 – τC)(1 + rd)(B0 /E0). (4.13) Finally, we can use the fact that V0U = V0 – τCB0 = E0 + B0 – τC B0 (this is just the present value of equation 4.10) to rewrite this as: re = ru + (1 – τC)(B0 / E0)(ru – rd). (4.14) Equation 4.14 is the MM 2nd proposition in the presence of corporate taxes. When τC = 0 this equation becomes identical to equation 4.9. However when τC > 0, the expected return on equity rises by less in comparison to equation 4.9 as leverage (B/E) increases. This is because 56 Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition even though extra leverage makes equity more risky for the same arguments as before, tax shield reduce some of this risk. This can also be seen by comparing the equity return in Figure 4.2 to that of Figure 4.3 which has the same returns in the presence of taxes. r rE After-tax WACC (1 – Tc) rD D E Figure 4.3: Weighted average cost of capital with tax. The MM 2nd proposition gives us a relationship between the unlevered return on a firm, and the return on the debt and equity of a similar but levered firm. The WACC is the average rate of return the firm pays to raise money, it is defined as a function of the returns on debt and equity. We can combine the MM 2nd proposition (equation 4.14) with the definition of WACC (equation 4.8) to find the WACC as a function of the unlevered return on the firm: WACC = ru(1 – τC (B0 / V0)). (4.15) Activity Combine equations 4.14 and 4.8 to derive equation 4.15. We can split up the risk investors of a firm face into two types of risk. The first is business risk, this depends on the risk of the firm’s underlying assets and activities. All similar firms should have similar business risk regardless of capital structure. The second is financial risk, this is additional risk that the firm faces due to its choice of capital structure. The return on an unlevered firm ru is based on the firm’s business risk, since this firm has no leverage. WACC is the return on the levered firm, this combines business and financial risk. From equation 4.15, it is evident that without taxes financial risk is irrelevant. The WACC of any firm is equal to the return on an unlevered firm, regardless of the amount of leverage. This is analogous to the 1st proposition of MM: the value of any firm is equal to the value of an unlevered firm, regardless of the amount of leverage. In the presence of taxes, the WACC decreases as we add leverage because of additional tax shields. With more leverage, the firm becomes safer, its borrowing rate decreases (equation 4.15), and its value increases. The MM 1st and 2nd propositions are flip sides of the same coin. Example Consider two firms with the same unlevered return on asset ru = 4.5 per cent. The corporate tax rate is 35 per cent. Firm A has no debt. Current pre-tax earnings are $23 million with no growth prospects. 57 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Firm B has AAA-rated long-term debt with 4 per cent yield to maturity and market value $50 million. Current pre-tax earnings are $8.75 million with no growth prospects. What are the WACC, equity return, total firm value, and equity value for each firm? The FCF of firm A is 23*(1 – .35) = $23.98 million. We use ru = 4.5% as the discount rate and find an unlevered firm value of VU = 23.98/.045 = $332.2 million. Since this firm is debt free, its equity value and its total value are the same as the unlevered value. Again, because this firm is unlevered, its WACC and its equity return are both equal to ru. The FCF of firm B is 8.75*(1 – 0.35) = $5.69 million. We use ru = 4.5% as the discount rate and find an unlevered firm value of VU = 5.69/ 0.045 = $126.4 million. Using the MM 1st proposition, we can calculate the levered value as the unlevered value plus the present value of tax shields where the present value of tax shields is given by τcB: V = 126.4 + 0.35*50 = $143.9 million. The equity value is the total firm value minus the value of the debt: 143.9 – 50 = $93.9 million. We can use the MM 2nd proposition (4.14) to calculate the return on equity: re = ru + (1 – τC)(B0 / E0)(ru – rd) = 4.5 + (1 – 0.35)*(50/93.9)*(4.5 – 4) = 4.67%. We can now calculate the WACC either through equation 4.8 or 4.15. Both give the same answer. First using equation 4.8: WACC = (E/(E + B))re + (1 – τC)(B/ (E + B))rd WACC = (50/143.9)*(1 – 0.35)*4 + (93.9/143.9)*4.67 = 3.95% Alternately using 4.15: WACC = ru(1 – τC(B/V)) = 4.5*(1 – 0.35*(50/143.9)) = 3.95%. A CAPM perspective (optional) So far we have looked at the relationships between returns implied by the Modigliani–Miller 2nd proposition. According to the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), the expected return of a security is linearly related to its correlation with the return on the market portfolio, one that comprises all assets in the market. This correlation is denoted by the betas of the securities, which reflect the correlation of the returns and the market risk premium, i.e. the expected return over and above the risk-free rate. The higher the beta of a security, the more correlated is the security with the market portfolio, and hence the higher the risk. To compensate investors for the higher risk, the security is expected to deliver a higher return. As a result, the relationship among the expected returns can be translated into the relationships between betas. A full understanding of CAPM is beyond this course (it is introduced in a typical asset pricing course). All we need to know is that the expected returns of the unlevered asset, equity, and risk-free bond returns vary linearly with the market risk premium and the coefficient is beta: ru = rf + βu (rm – rf) re = rf + βe (rm – rf) rd = rf + βd (rm – rf) (4.16) (4.17) (4.18) By plugging equation 4.16 into equation 4.14 (MM 2nd proposition) and then rearranging terms, we can rewrite the return on equity as: re = rf + [βu+ (1 – τC )(B/E)(βu – βd )](rm – rf) 58 (4.19) Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition This itself is a CAPM equation, by comparing equation 4.19 to 4.17 we can see that βe must equal to the term in brackets from equation 4.19: βe = βu + (1 – τC )(B/E)(βu – βd). (4.20) In the special case when the firm’s debt is riskless and therefore βd = 0, this equation simplifies to: βe = βu (1 + (1 – τC)(B/E)). (4.21) With equation 4.21 we can compare the β of an unlevered firm to the β of a levered firm. We can also use the equation backwards to find the unlevered β for a levered firm. Suppose you wish to find the expected equity return for a firm with no past financial data. It is possible to find a comparable publically trading firm with the same business risk (for example a firm in the same industry), however this firm may have different financial risk (different leverage). Using historical market information we can find the β of the comparable firm by running a regression of its excess return on the excess market return. (The regression is similar to equation 4.17.) The slope from this regression is the equity β of the comparable firm. However, due to different leverage, the β we are looking for may be different from this β. Using equation 4.21 with the capital structure of the publically traded firm, we can unlever this β and find the unlevered (asset) β, which is the same for both firms. We can then again use equation 4.21, this time with the leverage ratio of the firm whose β we wish to know, to get the desired equity β. Example Firm A is looking to do an IPO with a debt to value ratio of 0.7. The average equity beta of similar, publically traded firms is 0.85 and the average debt to value ratio is 0.22. The tax rate is 35 per cent. What rate of return should we use to discount Firm A’s expected equity cash flows? Using equation 4.21 backwards with the capital structure of the comparables, we find that the unlevered (asset) β of this industry is: βu = βe/(1 + (1 – τC)(B/E)) = 0.85/(1 + (1 – 0.35)*.22/(1 – 0.22)) = 0.718 Now we can use equation 4.21 forwards, with the target leverage of firm A: βe = βu(1 + (1 – τC)(B/E)) = 0.718*(1 + (1 – 0.35)* 0.7/(1 – 0.7)) = 1.81 With a 4 per cent historical risk-free rate and a 6 per cent historical market premium, the required equity return is: 4 + 1.81*6 = 14.86%. Summary In this chapter we derived relationships between the return on a firm’s equity, a firm’s debt and a firm’s total assets. We saw that if there are no taxes, increasing leverage makes equity riskier and increases expected returns. However, the return on the firm’s total assets does not change because more weight is given to the safe debt return. However, in the presence of taxes, the increase of expected equity returns with leverage was smaller, due to a tax refund. The return on the firm’s total asset actually declined with leverage in the presence of taxes, because tax refunds make the firm safer. This is analogous to firm value rising with leverage in the presence of taxes, as we saw in the previous chapter. 59 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Key terms business risk financial risk leverage tax shields weighted average cost of capital (WACC) unlevered (asset) return unlevered β A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: 60 • write down the relationship between debt, equity, the unlevered return on the firm, and the levered return on the firm • understand what happens to equity returns, and the weighted average cost of capital as leverage increases with and without taxes • draw a link between Modigliani and Miller’s 1st and 2nd propositions • find the equity beta of a firm by unlevering and relevering the equity beta of a comparable firm with different capital structure. Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition Sample examination questions 1. Consider an all equity firm with an equity β of 0.7. The risk-free rate is 3 per cent and the market risk premium is 6 per cent. The company is considering a recapitalisation to a debt-to-value ratio of 0.25; at this ratio the before-tax cost of debt will be 5 per cent. For a tax rate of 35 per cent, what is the WACC at this new level of leverage? 2. Stagnant Inc. is a swimming pool supply company that is currently unlevered with a P/E ratio of 12. The company has no growth prospects. The tax rate is 35 per cent. a. What is Stangant’s cost of capital? b. Stagnant is considering adopting a new capital structure with 50 per cent debt. It has consulted with a bank which is willing to lend at a 5 per cent rate. What will be the new return on equity, WACC and P/E ratio? 3. The earnings for firm A and firm B are given below (year –5 indicates 5 years ago, year 0 indicates this year’s dividend, which has not been paid out yet but is already known, year +1 indicates the forecast of next year’s dividend). All numbers are in millions of dollars. Year –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 +1 +2 A –11 0 1 2 21 22 23 23 B 5 13 7 4 15 13 3 10 4. Both firms pay out nearly 100 per cent of their after-tax cash flows to the owner. A has no debt. B has AAA-rated long-term debt with 4 per cent yield to maturity and market value of 50 million. The asset (unlevered) β for firms in the same industry as A and B is 0.5. The corporate tax rate is 35 per cent, assume no personal taxes. The historical risk-free rate is 3 per cent and the historical return on the stock market is 6 per cent. a. For each firm calculate the WACC, the firm (enterprise) value, and the equity value. Give justification for your calculation. b. What changes to capital structure would you make for firm A? Firm B? 61 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes 62 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to analyse and explain the choices of corporate capital structures made by firms’ managers through theories involving agency costs or asymmetries of information. Learning objectives By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • understand the concept of agency costs and governance problems in general • discuss the intuition behind the agency costs of debt, equity and free cash-flows • calculate the agency cost of debt in stylised settings • discuss the effects of asymmetric information on capital structure • explain the intuition behind the pecking order theory of finance. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 13 (Agency Problems, Management Compensation, and the Measurement of Performance) and 19 (How Much Should a Firm Borrow?). Further reading Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapter 15. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 16 (Bankruptcy Costs and Debt Holder – Equity Holder Conflicts), 17 (Capital Structure and Corporate Strategy), 18 (How Managerial Incentives Affect Financial Decisions) and 19 (The Information Conveyed by Financial Decisions). Jensen, M. ‘Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers’, American Economic Review 76(2) 1986, pp.323–29. Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976, pp.305–60. Masulis, R. ‘The impact of capital structure change on firm value: some estimates’, Journal of Finance 38(1) 1983, pp.107–26. Miller, M. ‘Debt and taxes’, Journal of Finance 32, 1977, pp.261–75. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporate finance and the theory of investment’, American Economic Review 48(3) 1958, pp.261–97. Myers, S. ‘Determinants of corporate borrowing’, Journal of Financial Economics 5(2) 1977, pp.147–75. Myers, S. and N. Majluf ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.187–221. 63 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Ross, S. ‘The determination of financial structure: the incentive signalling approach’, Bell Journal of Economics 8(1) 1977, pp.23–40. Overview In Chapter 3 we introduced the capital irrelevance proposition first put forward by Miller and Modigliani (1958). We also explored cases in which the capital structure of a firm did matter in its valuation due to relaxations of the MM assumptions (e.g. the introduction of corporation tax and bankruptcy costs). In this chapter we will focus on two classes of problem in which MM1 does not hold. In the first, firms are subject to agency problems between outside stakeholders and insiders (managers). The second class of problem allows the possibility that insiders to the firm are better informed about its quality than the market or potential external investors. Capital structure, governance problems and agency costs In most Western corporations, ownership and control are separate, in that the owners of a firm (the firm’s security-holders) entrust the day-to-day running of the firm to managers. In general, although owners may have an idea of what the optimal strategy for the firm is, it is impossible to force managers to follow this plan. Managers may then behave opportunistically, taking inflated salaries, investing in pet projects and enjoying other perquisites (perks). Hence, in such scenarios, managers can corporate policy to maximise their own utility rather than setting the policy which would maximise shareholder wealth. This is the agency problem that arises in modern corporations and was first talked about in relation to capital structure by Jensen and Meckling (1976). Agency costs of outside equity and debt Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that understanding of two types of agency cost is important in understanding why firm value is not invariant to capital structure. The first of these is an agency cost associated with outside equity. Assume a firm that is financed solely by equity. A proportion of the equity is held by the management of the firm, whereas the rest is held by outsiders to the firm. Jensen and Meckling argue that such a situation leads to firm values which are lower than that which would obtain if the manager was the sole owner of the firm. To see why this is the case, consider the rewards and costs facing the manager/equity-holder. The manager is the agent who undertakes activities that add value to the firm. Let’s call these activities ‘effort’. Increased effort supply leads to greater firm value and vice versa. However, supplying effort is also costly to the manager (it takes up their time and tires them mentally and physically, for example). In situations where a proportion α of the firm’s equity is held by outsiders, the manager bears the entire cost of effort supply but reaps only a portion (1 – α) of the benefit. Hence, the outside equity-holders gain from the manager increasing effort but don’t bear any costs. This induces the manager to supply lower levels of effort for higher values of α (i.e. when the proportion of profits the manager appropriates is low, their incentive is to supply little amounts of effort). Hence, firm value is decreased when the proportion of equity held by outsiders is increased, and MM1 does not hold. This is the agency cost of outside equity. 64 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure Jensen and Meckling argue that the agency cost of outside equity is decreasing in the leverage ratio of the firm (where leverage is the ratio of debt to equity values). The argument runs as follows: assume that the firm repurchases some of the equity held by outsiders, funding this with a debt issue – hence, leverage is increased. Also, the proportion of outstanding equity held by the manager is now increased. Thus, as his share of the residual value of the firm is increased, the manager chooses to supply more effort, leading to increased firm value. Then, as leverage rises, agency costs of outside equity fall. Example In this example we will see that when issuing outside equity, a project’s owner is worse off because she uses too little effort. On the other hand, when using debt, she uses optimal effort. Consider an entrepreneur with a project that next year pays $20 million with probability p and $10 million with probability 1 – p. This project requires an initial investment of $11 million. The entrepreneur can pick the probability of success p to be any number they want between 0.25 and 0.75. However, choosing a higher p requires effort e, which the entrepreneur dislikes; e = k*p. In this case k = 4 is the disutility of raising probability of success by 1 expressed in millions of dollars. In particular, if X is the monetary the utility function is: U = E[X] – k*e The required discount rate is zero and everyone is risk neutral. Suppose the entrepreneur finances the project with equity by promising a share α of equity to outside investors in return for them paying the $11 million necessary for the initial investment. Then their expected payoff is: E[X] = (1 – α)(20p + 10(1 – p)) = (1 – α)(10p + 10), and the utility is: U = E[X] – e = (1 – α)(10p + 10) – k*p = 10*(1 – α) + [10*(1 – α) – k]*p. Therefore, the entrepreneur will choose p to be as small as possible if 10*(1 – α ) – k < 0. Suppose outside investors believe that the entrepreneur will choose p = 0.75, then their expected payout is: α(0.75*20 + 0.25*10) = 17.5α. This must equal to their initial investment of 11, implying α = 62.9%. However, that implies that 10*(1 – α) – k = 3.71 – k < 0 and the entrepreneur would choose p = 0.25, therefore this cannot be an equilibrium. Suppose outside investors believe our investor will choose p = 0.25, then their expected payout is: α(0.25*20 + 0.75*10) = 12.5α. This must equal their initial investment of 11, implying α = 88%. Indeed 10*(1 – α) – k = 1.2 – k < 0, thus the entrepreneur will choose p = 0.25, consistent with the beliefs of outside equity-holders. The entrepreneur’s utility is: U = 10*(1 – α) + [10*(1 – α) – k]*p = 1.5 – k*p = 0.5. Suppose instead the entrepreneur financed this investment with debt by promising a face value F to creditors in return for $11 million to cover the initial investment. In this case the entrepreneur’s equity will always be bankrupt in the bad state of the world and they will receive zero; in this case creditors receive the full $10 million. In the good state of the world, the entrepreneur will receive 20 – F. Their utility is: U = E[X] – e = p(20 – F) – k*p = (20 – F – k)*p. They will choose p to be as large as possible as long as 20 – F – k > 0. 65 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Suppose creditors believe that p = 0.25. Then their expected payout is: p*F + (1 – p)*10 = 0.25F + 7.5 This must equal their initial investment of 11, implying F = 14. However, this implies that 20 – F – k > 0 and the entrepreneur would choose p = 0.75, therefore this cannot be an equilibrium. Suppose creditors believe that p = 0.75. Then their expected payout is: p*F + (1 – p)*10 = 0.75F + 2.5. This must equal to their initial investment of 11, implying F = 11.33. Indeed, 20 – F – k > 0 and the entrepreneur chooses p = 0.75, consistent with the beliefs of outside equityholders. The entrepreneur’s utility is: U = (20 – F – k)*p = 6.50 – k*p = 3.5. Note that this is much higher than when the entrepreneur uses equity. In this example the MM proposition did not hold because one type of security was better than another. As we increased the proportion of debt used to finance the firm, the entrepreneur chose to exert more effort and increased value. Increasing leverage reduced the agency cost of outside equity because it aligned the payoff to the entrepreneur with their cost of effort. With a fraction α of outside equity, for every dollar of value they took out of the firm due to decreased effort, the entrepreneur lost only (1 – α) of wealth. Activity First, show that in the above example, if the entrepreneur could commit to using the optimal amount of effort, then they could get maximum utility even when using equity. Next, show that in the above example if the entrepreneur is less averse to effort, for example k = 3, then two possible equilibria can arise in the equity financing case. Thus market beliefs may play an important role. The second agency cost highlighted by Jensen and Meckling is that associated with debt finance. It is also known as the asset substitution or risk-shifting problem associated with debt finance. To illustrate the problem, consider the following example. Example Assume that a firm that is financed by both debt and equity. A manager runs the firm in the interest of current equity-holders (i.e. the manager sets investment policy in order to maximise the expected shareholder payoff). The manager is faced with the choice between two investment projects, A and B. These projects are assumed to have zero cost and are mutually exclusive. The cash flows to projects A and B are given in Table 5.1. State 1 State 2 State 3 Probabilities 0.25 0.5 0.25 Cash flow A 40 50 60 Cash flow B 20 40 80 Table 5.1 Clearly, both projects have positive expected NPV. Project A has the lowest risk and the higher expected NPV (50), whereas project B is the riskier and its expected NPV is 45.1 We assume that debt-holders have a claim of 50 that must be repaid out of the cash flow to the chosen project. Given this debt claim, which project will the manager choose? 66 1 When we say that project B is riskier, we mean that it has higher cash-flow variance than project A. Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure Let us start our analysis with Project A. From the cash flows of the project, we see that, with a debt obligation of 50, only in state 3 will equityholders get any pay-off, this pay-off being 60 – 50=10. This implies that the expected pay-off from Project A to shareholders is 10*0.25 = 2.5. The expected pay-off to debt-holders from A is equal to (0.25*40) + (0.5*50) + (0.25*50) = 47.5. Moving on to the analysis of Project B, again equity-holders only get some cash in state 3 and their expected pay-off is 0.25*(80 – 50) = 7.5. The pay-off to debt-holders from Project B is (0.25*20) + (0.5*40) + (0.25*50) = 37.5. Hence, from the equity-holders point of view, Project B maximises expected pay-off as 7.5>2.5 and, as a result, this will be the project chosen by the manager. Note that the choice of this project implies that debt-holders are worse off and firm value lower than in the case where Project A is chosen. When the face value of debt is 50, the firm invests in the project with the lower expected NPV and higher risk, as this project maximises the expected return to equity. What would happen if the debt repayment outstanding were 30 instead of 50? In this case the expected payoffs to equity-holders are 20 from project A and 17.5 from project B. Therefore, the manager will choose project A. This choice also implies that debtholders are happy as project A maximises their expected payoff (they get 30 rather than the 27.5 that they would expect to receive if project B were chosen). Note that, when the face value of debt is lower, the manager switches and chooses the low-risk, high-expected-return project. This, in turn, implies that, when face value of debt is lower, firm value is higher. Example In this example we will see that when issuing debt, a project’s owner is worse off because they choose to take on too much risk. On the other hand, when using outside equity, they choose the optimal amount of risk. Consider an entrepreneur with a choice of one of two projects. Project A pays $5 million or $15 million with equal probability. Project B pays 0 or $18 million with equal probability. Each project requires an initial investment of $3 million. The entrepreneur will have the freedom to choose the project after they raise financing. The required discount rate is zero and everyone is risk neutral. There are no taxes or bankruptcy costs. Note that the expected value of project A is 0.5*5 + 0.5*15 = 10 while the expected value of project B is 0.5*0 + 0.5*18 = 9 so project A is better. Project A is also less volatile; in this example investors are risk neutral but typically they would prefer less volatile projects. Consider debt financing. For any face value of debt F shareholders receive the residual after creditors have been paid. From project A their expected payout is: 0.5*(5 – F) + 0.5*(15 – F) = 10 – F if F < 5 0.5*0 + 0.5*(15 – F) = 7.5 – 0.5F if 5 < F < 15. From project B their expected payout is: 0.5*(18 – F) = 9 – 0.5F if F < 18. Comparing these two equations we can see that project B is preferred by equity-holders for any F > 2, this can also be seen graphically in Figure 8.1. Project B is preferred because equity-holders have a limited downside but care very much about the upside. On the other hand, creditors expected payout from project A is: 67 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance F if F < 5 0.5*5 + 0.5*F = 2.5 + 0.5F if 5 < F < 15. From project B their expected payout is: 0.5*F if F < 18. Comparing these two equations we can see that project A is preferred by creditors for any F, this can also be seen graphically in Figure 8.1. Project A is preferred because creditors have no upside, and care only about limiting losses in the downside. Since the necessary initial investment is 3, the face value of debt will have to be at least 3. This leads equity-holders to choose project B. Knowing this, creditors will ask for a face value of debt such that they receive their initial investment back in expectation: 3 = 0.5*F and F = 6. With this F, the initial entrepreneur’s payout is: 0.5*(18 – 6) = $6 million Suppose the entrepreneur could credibly commit to choose project A. In that case creditors would ask for a smaller face value of debt, F = 3, because even in the bad scenario, project A will be more than enough to repay the initial investment. The payout to equity-holders would be: 10 – F = $7 million. The shareholders would be better off if they could ex-ante commit to invest in A because A has higher NPV. However, as we saw earlier, with F = 3 they are ex-post better off choosing B. Since the creditors have no reason to trust them, creditors will assume B will be chosen and ask for F = 6. Now consider using outside equity to finance this project. Outside equity-holders are promised a fraction α of the project and the entrepreneur receives the rest. The entrepreneur’s payoff from choosing A is: (1 – α)[0.5*5 + 0.5*15] = (1 – α)*10, and from choosing B it is: (1 – α)[0.5*0 + 0.5*18] = (1 – α)*9. Clearly the entrepreneur always chooses A. Knowing this, outside equity-holder will ask for α such that their expected payoff 10α is equal to their initial investment of 3. This implies that α = 30% and the entrepreneur’s share is worth (1 – 0.3)*10 = 7. This is just as good as the commitment case and better than the debt financing case. In this example the MM proposition did not hold because one type of security was better than another. Debt financing caused the entrepreneur to choose a very risky project (risk shift) because their downside was limited. As a result, creditors asked for a very high interest rate to protect their investment and the entrepreneur was worse off for this. Equity financing did not face this problem because the entrepreneur was just receiving a fixed share of total profits, therefore it was in their interest to maximise total profits both ex-ante and ex-post. Commitment was a possible substitute to equity, but it may be difficult to implement in a real world situation. 68 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure Shareholder value 10 Project A Project B 5 Creditor value 0 0 5 10 F 15 20 10 8 6 4 25 Project A Project B 2 0 0 5 10 F 15 20 25 Figure 5.1: Payoff to the shareholder and to the creditor. Jensen and Meckling argue that the agency costs of debt are increasing in the level of debt outstanding and hence in corporate leverage. Combining the two agency costs then allows us to argue that an optimal (in the sense of maximising firm value) capital structure might exist. We contended that the agency cost of outside equity was decreasing in leverage, whereas the agency cost of debt increased with leverage. Firm value would be maximised where total agency costs are minimised, and this leads to the optimal leverage ratio shown on Figure 5.2. Cost Total cost Cmin Agency cost of debt 0 Agency cost of equity D/E* D/E Figure 5.2: Optimal leverage under agency costs. The Myers (1977) debt overhang problem Another agency cost of debt was pointed out by Myers (1977). Rather than arguing that debt obligations induce managers to invest in excessively risky projects, Myers argues that the management of firms with large levels of debt outstanding will choose to reject some positive NPV projects. As a result, heavily indebted firms will see reductions in corporate value, and MM1 is violated. This is known as the debt overhang problem. To illustrate the previous argument consider the situation depicted in Table 5.2. A given firm is presented with the opportunity to invest in a certain project at the current time. The payoff of this investment is $20,000 at time t + 1 regardless of the state of nature, and the cost at time t is $10,000. We assume, for simplicity, that interest rates are zero such that the investment has a positive NPV. Further, the firm receives cash flow at time t, which reflects its past investments. This cash flow is uncertain. As depicted in Table 5.2, with probability 0.25 it will be $50,000; it will be $80,000 with probability 0.5 and, finally, with probability 0.25 it will be $120,000. 69 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance The firm is run by a manager who acts in the interest of current shareholders. In the past, the firm issued debt with a face value of $100,000. This debt must be repaid out of the cash flow to the firm, after the investment decision has been made and any payoffs realised. Note that, if the project is accepted by the manager, its cost must be met out of the pockets of equity-holders. State 1 State 2 State 3 0.25 0.5 0.25 Cash flow existing assets 50 80 120 Cost new project 10 10 10 Return new project 20 20 20 Probabilities Table 5.2 When the face value of debt is $100,000, the manager will reject the new project. Why is this? Note that, in states 1 and 2, the new project pays $20,000, but this simply goes straight into the pockets of debt-holders through the required payment of $100,000. It is only in state 3 that the $20,000 payoff of the new project accrues to equity-holders. Hence, in this case the expected net payoff to equity-holders is: (0.25 * 20) – 10 = –5. As this is negative, the manager rejects the new project. The implication of this is that, when debt levels are high, a firm may reject a project with positive NPV, as little of that project’s payoff accrues to equity-holders. To confirm this, consider the case in which the required debt payment is $80,000 rather than $100,000. In this case, the payoff from existing assets is sufficient to service the debt in both states 2 and 3. Hence, in both these states the equity-holders reap all of the rewards from the new project, whereas the new project payoff goes to debt-holders in state 1. Hence, the expected net return to equity-holders from the new project is: (0.5*20) + (0.25*20) – 10 = 5. As this is positive, the manager will accept the project as it increases expected shareholder wealth. Activity Compute the expected payoff to equity-holders if the required debt repayment is 90. Will the manager accept or reject the project? The preceding example illustrates the debt overhang argument. Managers that run heavily indebted corporations in the interest of equity-holders may reject positive NPV projects as the cash flows from such projects accrue mostly to debt-holders, whereas equity-holders bear the costs. The rejection of such projects implies that firm values are suboptimal. Agency costs of free cash flows Although debt may generate agency costs, as discussed in the previous section, Jensen (1986) argues that debt may also alleviate agency costs of free cash flows. In this framework, debt is valuable as it motivates managers to disgorge cash (in the form of interest and principal payments) rather than investing it at below the cost of capital or wasting it on organisation inefficiencies. Jensen argues that growth is associated with increases in managers’ compensation and power. Managers have thus incentives to grow their 70 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure firms beyond their optimal size; that is, to engage in ‘empire-building’. Managers of firms with substantial free cash flow, that is, cash flows in excess of that required to fund all projects with non-negative NPVs, are thus tempted to invest it at below the cost of capital or waste it on organisation inefficiencies rather than return the cash to shareholders through the payment of dividends or repurchase of shares. The agency cost of free cash flows is the negative NPV of the investments made at below the cost of capital. In this context, debt creation, without the retention of the proceeds of the issue, enables managers to bond their promise to pay out future cash flows in the form of interest and principal payments. Although increases in dividends can be reversed, an issue of debt used to repurchase equity is a credible bond as debt-holders are given the right to take the firm into bankruptcy court if managers do not respect their promise to make interest and principal payments. Debt thus reduces the agency costs of free cash flow by decreasing the cash flow available for spending at the discretion of managers. Firm value and asymmetric information The preceding sections emphasised the point that agency problems may lead to departures from MM1. An alternative reason for such departures is the presence of information asymmetries between corporate insiders and outsiders. The role played by asymmetric information is emphasised by Ross (1977) and Myers and Majluf (1984). Ross (1977) signalling argument for debt The crux of Ross’ argument is as follows. Assume firms differ according to their future cash-flow prospects. High-quality firms expect large future cash flows, whereas low-quality firms expect cash flows to be small. Firm quality is not observable to outsiders to the firm. The managers of highquality firms have an incentive to attempt to signal their quality to the market, as in the absence of signals the market can’t distinguish high- and low-quality firms and will value them identically. One way the management can signal is through debt policy. High-quality firms choose large leverage ratios and lower quality firms choose low leverage ratios. The market can observe leverage and hence values firms accordingly (assigning firm values increasing in leverage.) Leverage is a credible signal, as it is assumed that firm managers are averse (in terms of their own utility) to bankruptcy. High levels of debt imply a higher probability of bankruptcy, and only managers in charge of high-quality firms are willing to expose themselves to this probability. The preceding intuition can be formalised with the following model, which is a simplified version of that contained in Ross (1977). Assume a population of firms, each of which has future cash flow that is uniformly distributed.2 Firm quality varies, as the upper bound of the cash flow distribution (call this parameter t) varies across firms (i.e. a high-quality firm may have cash flow distributed on [0, t1] and a low-quality firm might have cash flow distributed on [0, t2] where t1 exceeds t2). Managers of firms know the value of t for their own firms, but the market as a whole does not. Managerial utility is increasing in date 0 firm value and date 1 firm value, but is decreasing in the expected cost of bankruptcy. In line with the prior argument, managers will try to use debt to signal their quality. However, non-zero debt levels imply that bankruptcy is possible. Hence, we can write the managerial optimisation problem as follows: 2 If cash flow is uniformly distributed on [a, b] it means that the probability density of cash flow is constant from a to b and zero elsewhere. This implies that the probability distribution function of cash flow is F(x)=(x–a)/ (b–a) for x between a and b. 71 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance (5.1) where we have assumed firm quality of t, V0(B) is date 0 firm value, L is a parameter reflecting the cost (in managerial utility terms) of bankruptcy and γ is a weight parameter. Given that the manager knows the true t distribution of firm cash flow, his assessment of date 1 firm value is 2 . Similarly, if a debt level of B is chosen, the manager knows the firm will be B bankrupt with probability t and the expected utility cost of bankruptcy is hence . Assume that the market assigns a firm with debt level B a date 0 value of f(B). Substituting this into equation 5.1 gives: (5.2) To compute the optimal level of debt, we compute the first order condition of 5.2 with respect to B. After rearrangement this yields: . (5.3) Finally, we assume that in equilibrium, the market’s beliefs about firm quality (based on a firm’s debt level) are correct. Hence, we have the condition f (B(t)) = 2t where we have also acknowledged the dependence of the debt level, B, on firm quality through managerial actions. Differentiating this condition yields: f’(B)B’(t) = ½. (5.4) Substituting f’(B) from 5.4 into 5.3 yields the following differential equation: . (5.5) This differential equation has the following general solution: (5.6) where c is a constant term. The constant c can be assigned a value through noting that the lowest quality firm in the population has no incentive to signal and will hence elect not to have any debt. Denoting the lowest quality by tc, use of this intuition in 5.6 gives: (5.7) . Substitution of 5.7 in 5.6 gives the final debt rule: . (5.8) Equation 5.8 gives us the key results from the Ross (1977) model. Debt level (B) is increasing in firm quality (t). Clearly then, firms with higher debt levels will have greater date 0 market values and MM1 is violated once more. In more loose terms, the arguments in Ross (1977) are that debt is a costly signal (due to the possibility of bankruptcy it entails), and hence its use implies higher-quality firms. From an empirical standpoint, evidence that supports this notion can be found in Masulis (1983). This paper demonstrates that firms which swap debt for equity (hence increasing leverage) experience positive stock price returns whereas firms swapping equity for debt experience negative stock returns. The stock price reactions 72 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure are interpreted as implying that leverage-increasing transactions are good news whereas leverage-decreasing transactions are bad news, consistent with the asymmetric information story. The Myers–Majluf (1984) pecking order theory of finance Another study that generates departures from MM1 through information asymmetries is Myers and Majluf (1984). Although Ross focuses on the level of the debt–equity ratio as a signal of firm quality, Myers–Majluf concentrate on the information revealed by security issues. The intuition behind their arguments is as follows. We start by assuming a population of firms differing in both the quality (value) of their assets in place and the quality (NPV) of their investment projects. Any investment project has to be financed through an issue of equity. Assume also that the managers of any firm are better informed about both the quality of their firm’s assets in place and the quality of their firm’s investment project than are outsiders. Furthermore, assume that managers act in the interests of their firm’s existing equity-holders. Only managers know whether the equity of their firm is over- or underpriced though, and this creates an opportunity for them to exploit the market in order for existing shareholders to profit. The existence of information asymmetries thus implies that the market can misprice corporate equity: some firms’ equity may be over priced and others will be under priced. In this setting, managers may raise equity for two reasons. • They may wish to invest in a positive NPV investment, which would result in an increase in the value of the firm’s equity. • Alternatively, they may wish to issue overpriced equity, which would result in a transfer of wealth from the new to the old equity-holders. Given rational expectations, the financial market correctly recognises both incentives to raise equity. In equilibrium, managers of low-quality firms (i.e. managers of firms with assets in place whose true worth is low enough – and are hence overvalued), raise equity in order to take projects with a small but negative NPV. The benefit to the existing equity-holders that results from issuing overvalued equity exceeds the cost resulting from taking the negative NPV project. Similarly, managers of high-quality firms (i.e. managers of firms with assets in place whose true worth is high enough – and are hence undervalued), abstain from raising equity and hence from taking projects with a small but positive NPV. The dilution to the existing equity-holders that results from issuing undervalued equity exceeds the benefit resulting from the positive NPV generated by taking the project. The presence of information asymmetries between managers and equity-holders hence leads to distortions in investments. Issue decisions affect prices as they reveal information on firm quality. Managers are more likely to issue equity when their firm’s assets in place are overvalued, as opposed to undervalued. On average, equity issues thus lead to stock price drops. Furthermore, the highest quality firms avoid issues at all costs. Generalising the above somewhat, we can fit riskless debt, risky debt and other securities into our pecking order. Obviously, issuing riskless debt to finance investments conveys no information to the market, as there is no possibility of exploitation (as there is no risk). Thus, stock prices should not react to riskless debt issues and the highest quality firms will issue riskless debt in order to finance any investments. Low-quality firms don’t issue riskless debt, as they cannot exploit new investors through its issue. Risky 73 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance debt comes with a possibility of default and hence could be overpriced if the market underestimates the probability of default. Issues of risky debt, therefore, convey some information, but clearly less than issues of equity. Putting this all together leads to a model in which equity issues cause stock prices to drop a lot (as the market infers that firms that issue are very poor quality), risky debt issues cause small price decreases (as fairly low-quality firms issue risky debt) and riskless debt issues cause no price impact (as only high-quality firms issue riskless debt). Hence, in a dynamic sense, Myers–Majluf implies that capital structure decisions do affect firm values. This is the pecking order theory of finance. There is a fair amount of empirical evidence that supports the pecking order theory. First, the event study results on exchange offers detailed above are consistent with the pecking order theory. Second, event study evidence on new security issues confirms the theory too. Common stock issues lead to price impacts of around –3 per cent, for example, whereas risky debt issues cause small price drops, which are not statistically different from zero. Hence, the intuition that underlies the model is regarded by many as very plausible. Example Project Universe Industries (PUI), an all equity firm, currently has 20 million shares outstanding. The value of the company is the sum of the value of the assets in place and the NPV of the project. As shown in the following table, both the value of the assets in place and the NPV from the project crucially depend on the price of oil: Valuation Assets State A (cheap oil) State B (expensive oil) Assets in place £130m £220m NPV of the project’s cash flows £10m £40m The positive NPV project requires an initial investment of K = £600m irrespective of the state of nature. In order to fund its project, PUI must raise £600m in equity. Assume that managers maximise the wealth of the existing shareholders and that the states are equally likely. a. If managers must issue equity prior to knowing the price of oil, how many shares should the firm issue and at which price will they sell for? In each state, the post-issue firm value will be equal to the sum of the value of the assets in place, the NPV of the project, and the capital (K = $600m) contributed by the new equity-holders. In state A, the post-issue firm value is thus £740m. In state B, the post-issue firm value is thus £860m. As both states are equally likely, the expected post-issue firm value is thus £800m (derived as 50%*£740m + 50%*£860m). The fraction of the value of the firm that the new shareholder should be getting is hence £600m/£800m = 75%. The value of the firm’s equity prior to the share issue is thus £600m, and the share price is thus £200m/20m = £10. As ex-post, all the shares have an equal claim, the firm must thus issue 60 million new shares (derived as £600m/£10). b. If the manager knew the state of the world before investing, in which state (A or B) would the manager raise equity and invest in the project? In order to answer this question, let us assume that the capital can be raised under the terms found in part a) of this example and that the market does not know the state of the world. Let us derive the ex-post payoffs to the existing shareholders in each state of nature when the manager raises equity and invests in the project and when the manager abstains from raising any equity and does not invest in the project. These payoffs can be found in the following table: 74 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure Payoff to existing shareholders Do nothing Issue equity invested in the project State A (cheap oil) State B (expensive oil) £130m £220m (1 – 75%) * £740m (1 – 75%) * £860m Table 5.3 The manager, when informed about the realisation of the state of nature, will issue equity and invest in the positive NPV project in state A as (1 − 75%)*£740m = £185m is strictly higher than £130m and refrain from issuing equity and forego the positive NPV project in state B as (1 − 75%)*£860m = £215m is strictly lower than £220m. The manager of the firm hence abstains from issuing any equity and does not invest in the strictly positive NPV project in the favourable state of nature. The intuition behind this result is as follows. Although taking this project would increase the value of the firm overall as it has a strictly positive NPV, it also leads to a reduction in the wealth of the existing shareholders. The reason for this is that, in the favourable state of nature, the financial market undervalues both the NPV of the project and the intrinsic value of the firm’s existing assets. The effect of the dilution of the existing shareholders, resulting from issuing undervalued shares, turns out to be so high that the existing shareholders are better off without the project whenever the project has to be financed through outside equity. c. Now let us assume that the market knows that managers will make a decision after observing the state of the world. When managers announce that they will not issue equity to fund the project, the stock price of the firm may change. How would you expect it to change? In order to answer this question, let us assume that the firm does not have any other source of capital to take the project and that the market does not know the state of the world. Upon the announcement that equity will not be issued and the investment project will not be taken, the market updates its estimate of the value of the firm, infers that state B is obtaining, and hence prices the firm’s stock at £11 per share (£220m/20m), hence rises by 10 per cent. Summary In this chapter we have examined theoretical models (and examples), which imply that firm value does depend on the financing choices it makes and on capital structure choices in particular. First, we examined arguments based on agency costs and then looked at a model of asymmetric information. The empirical evidence for these models is mixed. Evidence for agency problems can be found in the specification of corporate debt contracts, which contain clauses aimed specifically at preventing debt overhang and asset substitution problems. The previously discussed evidence on exchange offers is supportive of asymmetric information models (although it would contradict the implications of a debt overhang model). Research in these areas still proceeds. The most recent strand of literature on capital structure builds on the agency cost approach and examines incomplete contracts as the source of violations of MM1. 75 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Key terms agency costs of debt agency costs of free cash flows agency costs of outside equity asset substitution problem asymmetric information capital structure debt-overhang problem event study governance problems overinvestment pecking order theory risk-shifting problem separation of ownership and control signalling underinvestment A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • understand the concept of agency costs and governance problems in general • discuss the intuition behind the agency costs of debt, equity and free cash-flows • calculate the agency cost of debt in stylised settings • discuss the effects of asymmetric information on capital structure • explain the intuition behind the pecking order theory of finance. Sample examination questions 1. Explain the debt-overhang problem. 2. What are the agency costs of equity? Explain. 3. A firm has £100m in cash on hand and a debt obligation of £100m due next period. With this cash, it can take one of two projects (A and B) which cost £100m each. Assume that the firm cannot raise any additional funds. If the economy is favourable, project A will pay £120m and project B will pay £101m. If the economy is unfavourable, project A will pay £60m and project B will pay £101m. Assume that investors are risk-neutral, there are no taxes or direct costs of bankruptcy, the risk-free rate of interest is nil, and the probability of each state of nature obtaining is equal. a. What is the NPV of each project? b. Which project will equity-holders want the firm’s manager to take? c. Show that debt-holders would find it incentive-compatible to cut the face value of their claim to £82m. 76 Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure 4. What are the consequences of asymmetries of information between managers and investors, as in Myers and Majluf, for investments and the funding of investments? 5. Consider an entrepreneur who has a project that will cost $20 million to implement and will produce cash flows of either $3 million or $5 million per year in perpetuity with equal probability. The entrepreneur does not have the $20 million and must raise it externally. Assume risk neutrality and a 10 per cent opportunity cost of capital. a. Calculate the annual cash flow to the entrepreneur and its present value if they raise the $20 million through perpetual debt. b. Calculate the annual cash flow to the entrepreneur and its present value if they raise the initial investment with equity. c. As CEO of the firm the entrepreneur is able to spend $200,000 per year on a marketing relationship with their favourite celebrity. This advertising relationship is worth only $150,000 annually for a net loss of $50,000. However, the CEO receives utility from the relationship, in particular, they would be willing to spend up to $30,000 of their own money purely to spend time with this celebrity. Show that if the entrepreneur uses equity to raise money, they will engage in the wasteful advertising relationship but if they use debt, they will not. d. Suppose the outside investors are aware of the CEO’s penchant for spending time with celebrities. What share of equity would they demand? What would be the present value of the entrepreneur’s total payoff? 5. A firm’s productive assets will be worth either $100 million in a good state or $10 million in a bad state with equal probability. Additionally, the firm has $15 million in cash, which it could pay out as a dividend, and outstanding debt with a face value of $35 million due next year. The firm also has a project which would require an investment of $15 million this year and produce $22 million with certainty regardless of the state of the world. Assume risk neutrality and a 10% cost of capital. a. Do stockholders choose to take this positive NPV project? What is the present value of the creditors payoff? b. Suppose creditors suggest to financially restructure by reducing the face value of debt to 24 if the shareholders promise to use the $15 million to invest. Will the shareholders agree? Will the creditors prefer to do this? 77 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes 78 Chapter 6: Equity financing Chapter 6: Equity financing Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to understand and analyse several different ways to issue new equity, some prominent features in equity offerings, and wellknown frictions associated with equity issuance. With this aim in mind, we study staged financing in the private equity market, initial public offerings, seasoned equity offerings, rights offerings, and the winner’s curse problem. Learning objectives At the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain venture capital and equity issuance in the public market • perform valuation with multiple financing rounds • explain the calculate ownership structure in initial public offerings and seasoned equity offerings • explain and evaluate the winners’ curse problem. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 15 (How Corporations Issue Securities). Further reading Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 3 (Equity Financing) Rock, K. ‘Why new issues are underpriced’, Journal of Financial Economics 15 (1–2) 1986, pp.187–212. Introduction Corporate finance is mostly about how firms raise money to conduct their activities. Broadly speaking, there are two categories of financing securities: debt and equity. Financing a project through debt results in a liability to creditors that can take the form of a bank loan, notes payable or bonds issued to the public. This is an obligation that must be serviced, independent of the project’s success as debt holders are senior to equity holders. Debt comes with benefits for the firm (tax shield, less information sensitive claim), but it might also cause conflicts of interest (recall the debt overhang problem in Chapter 5), and as a result, some positive NPV projects might not get financed. Equity financing is usually in the form of selling company shares to investors. It is less risky than debt with respect to cash flow commitments, but causes a dilution of share ownership and control. Moreover, equity holders are junior claimholders compared to debt holders. In Chapters 3–5, we focused on debt financing. Now we will turn to equity financing. In this chapter, we will consider three main topics. First, we will see how start-up companies finance themselves. We will talk about the main stages of equity financing and their characteristics. Then, we will analyse how 79 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance firms issue new shares. Our main focus will be IPO (initial public offering) and SEO (seasoned equity offerings). Finally, we will consider one of the most prominent features in IPO market – underpricing – and one of its explanations. Private equity financing In this section, we will consider the main features of private equity. We will focus on venture capitalists. First, we will talk about the main characteristics of these funds. Then, we will see how they provide financing to firms, and why they have the incentives to monitor the firms. Last, we will talk about the typical VC structure and the compensation scheme. Consider a small start-up company. Suppose you have a brilliant idea in mind. How do you finance your endeavor? Young small firms often begin with self-financing: equity and ‘informal finance’, debt from family, friends. As the firm grows, the ability/willingness of informal finance fails to meet the needs of the business and firms look for other sources of financing. There are three main ways companies finance their future operations: • retained earnings • bank debt • private equity. We say that firms use retained earnings for financing if they reinvest their profits. This might appear to be the easiest and most natural source of funds for the firm, but clearly the amount of money may not be enough, especially, for fast-growing companies. The next source of financing is banks. This is the predominate source of small-business finance but there are limits here as well. Banks usually require tangible assets and/ or performance records. However, typically young firms often do not meet the eligibility criteria and fail to obtain bank financing. The alternative is private equity – equity financing that is not publicly traded. This type of financing usually comes from venture capitalists (VCs). Venture capital is one increasingly important alternative institution specialising in financing risky and opaque firms. Let us consider the key features. First, it is an equity investor, and hence inherits all the characteristics of equity holders. This is in contrast to bank investors, who are debt holders. Second, as outlined above, VCs invest in risky firms. Hence, they have a low success probability but much higher than usual returns (recall the usual risk-return trade-off: higher risk should be compensated by higher returns). Third, venture capital comes in the form of staged financing – funds are usually dispersed in stages, after a certain level of success is achieved. Finally, VCs are active investors. They usually hold a large stake in the firm and have incentive to monitor/ advise the start-up company. Let us now elaborate on the last two features — staged financing and active investors. Why do VCs use staged financing? Why don’t they just finance the projects by giving entrepreneurs a lump sum? Let us think about it. If the VC gives a lot of money to young small firms at once, that creates several problems. For example, the entrepreneur might have no incentive to develop their idea, and can simply abandon the project. Alternatively, they can take riskier decisions. In other words, providing all the funds at once creates higher risks for the VC. Using staged financing allows the VC to minimise the risk. If the small firm fails to meet the eligibility criteria 80 Chapter 6: Equity financing for the next financing stage, the VC can cut financing or even withdraw from the project. This creates strong incentives for entrepreneurs to be more efficient in order to get to the next financing stage. Essentially, staged financing creates real options for the VC by providing them with the flexibility to adjust funding decisions in the future. If the new firms are unsuccessful, the VC has the option to abandon the project. If the firms turn out to be successful, the VC has the option to expand profitable projects by injecting more money. How does one calculate the ownership structure with multiple rounds of equity finance? Let us take a simple example. You have just started your own company (say, a website or a social network) by investing $K. For simplicity, there were no sunk costs related to setting up the company, so the company is also worth $K. After some time, you realise you need new funding to expand the operations, for example to buy new servers or hardware. You present your business plan to a couple of potential investors, and one of them, impressed by your presentation, decides to contribute $L to the company. Now, the firm is worth $K+$L, and your K fraction of the firm is s = . After some more time, your website K+ L gets even more popular and attracts the attention of a VC. The VC decides to contribute $X to your startup. After contribution, the startup is worth $V=$K+$L+$X. As an original investor (OI), you hold 0 < s < 1 fraction of the precontribution firm. What fraction of the post-contribution company do you (OI) and the VC own? The VC simply owns $X in something worth $V, so x his fraction is VCfrac = . The OI owns a fraction s of whatever is left v x in the company, excluding the VC’s share: OIfrac= s *[1 – . As the OI v ] attracts more and more funds from outside investors, the value of the firm keeps growing, but your fraction decreases, everything else equal. Let us illustrate the staged financing with an example where we will see how to calculate the fraction of the company that belongs to different investors in each stage.– ( ( Example. Staged finance We decide to start our own company by investing $2K of our own money at the beginning. The firm is all-equity financed, with a value of $2K. After a year, a VC contributes another $2K, and our company is worth $4K. However, our own share drops from 100 per cent originally, to 50 per cent (see Table 6.1). Assets Liabilities Cash from new equity 2.0 New equity from venture capital 2.0 Other assets 2.0 Your original equity 2.0 Value 4.0 Value 4.0 Table 6.1: First stage market value balance sheet ($K). Your fraction: 2 4 = 50% 2 (Recall that if the VC contributes X to a start-up 4 = 50% worth V, his fractions is simply X/V. Here X=2 and V=4) VC1 fraction: Suppose we expand the business and in one year the market value increases to $20K. A new VC2 contributes $8K. 81 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Assets Liabilities Cash from new equity 8.0 New equity from 2nd stage 8.0 Fixed assets 2.0 Equity from 1st stage ?? Other assets 18.0 Your original equity ?? Value 28.0 Value 28.0 Table 6.2: Second stage market value balance sheet ($K). 8 28 = 29% VC1 fraction: half the old firm = ½ (1 − 29%) = 35% of the new firm VC2 fraction: To calculate your fraction, we use s=1/2 as you had 1/2 of the company at the first stage, and X/V = 29% – the share of the new VC: X s ∗ [1− ( )] = ½ (1 − 29%) = 35% ($10K) V VCs often specialise in certain industries or in a certain stage of firms. In practice, many VCs focus on high-tech high growth industries such as information technology, biotechnology, etc. These industries are opaque and very risky, since it is not so straightforward to calculate the value of new products and ideas in these areas. Many of these firms have very low success probability – usually only two out of 10 turn out to be profitable investments. As discussed before, VCs have low success probability but larger than usual return on the firms that turn out to be profitable. A typical stage list is: • Angel investor: Usually the firm has only raw ideas at this stage and there is no product yet. • Seed capital: There is a prototype of the product and a business plan to illustrate the main ideas. • Early stage venture capital: At this stage, the firm starts to generate revenue but is still perhaps not profitable. • Late stage venture capital: The company is profitable but needs additional cash to invest. • Mezzanine stage: This is the last stage before IPO (VC exit). Often, there are multiple securities used for financing: debt, convertibles and so on. Now, let us move on to the last feature of VCs – active investors. Recall that private equity is equity financing that is not publicly traded. Compared to public equity, there are two main differences. First, private equity is not as easily tradable as public equity. Private equity projects are often illiquid as VCs usually know much better about the quality of the project compared to outside investors. Hence, it might be hard for VCs to sell their stake to the general public. Public equity in this sense is more liquid. Second, private equity is characterised by concentrated large investors, compared to the dispersed and small owners of large public companies. This creates some problems. Usually, the many small owners of public equity have no skill or incentive to monitor the company. They have to exert the full cost of monitoring, but enjoy only a very small fraction of the benefits. This is called externality: one does not fully bear the 82 Chapter 6: Equity financing consequences of one’s action. Hence, it is rational for them to not monitor (as the costs exceed the benefits). This is the famous free-riders problem. VCs can solve this problem. They are big shareholders of a company, so they enjoy a big part of the benefits from monitoring. Hence, for them, it is rational to monitor the entrepreneur (benefits exceed the costs). Let us illustrate this intuition in a simple case where we will see why small investors have no incentive to monitor, whereas large investors have. Example. VC monitoring Suppose there is a firm that next period generates a cash flow of 10 if an equity holder monitors or 0 otherwise. The cost of monitoring is 4. If you are a small investor with 20 per cent stake, then you do not monitor because: • The payoff from monitoring is 20%*10 – 4 = –2 (if you monitor, then the firm value is 10, and you get 20 per cent of the total firm value. On the other hand, you exert monitoring effort of 4 – the full cost of monitoring. Hence, the net payoff to you as the monitoring shareholder is: 20%*10 – 4 = –2). • On the other hand, your payoff from not monitoring is simply 0 as the firm value without monitoring is 0. Since your payoff from not monitoring exceeds the one from monitoring (0>–2), you do not monitor. If every investor holds less than 20 per cent, then no one monitors. In public companies, this is almost always true, so we have the free-riders problem. On the other hand, if you are a large investor with a 70 per cent stake, then you will monitor because: • you anticipate that no one else monitors • your payoff from monitoring is: 70%*10 – 4 = 3 • payoff from not monitoring is 0<3. Thus, you are better off monitoring. VCs are usually large investors with a big stake in the company; hence, they have the incentives to monitor. Now, let us talk about how VC funds raise money for their investments. VCs belong to the private equity industry and are usually organised in limited partnership structure. There are two types of partners: general partners (GPs) and limited partners (LPs). GPs are responsible for choosing and monitoring the portfolio of firms. They contribute mainly skill and around 2 per cent of the total capital of the VC. LPs provide capital for the partnership. They do not directly make investment decisions but contribute the majority of capital: around 98 per cent. To understand the fund structure, let us consider the following example. Suppose you have brilliant skills in choosing successful start-ups, but do not have enough money to invest in all of them. However, some outside investors (for example your friends) have large amounts of money and are looking for high return projects. One possibility is to set up a VC, where you are the GP and your wealthy investors are the LPs. A typical fund structure is depicted in Figure 6.1. The institutional investors are the LPs – they contribute funds to the VC and expect larger than usual returns. The VCs are the GPs – they buy the equity of a portfolio of start-ups. 83 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Institutional Investors Returns Funds VCs Cash Equity Portfolio Firms Figure 6.1: Typical VC structure. Now let us talk about the benefits of the VC structure. Private equity funds are limited-duration funds – they normally last for 10–12 years. The limited duration provides a strong incentive for the GP to perform well because it would be much harder to raise money for the next fund without a good track record. For example, new LPs would be reluctant to contribute funds to GPs that performed poorly in previous venture capital situations. Private equity funds are a closed-end type of funds. This means that no shares can be redeemed or created after the fund is structured. If, for example, the fund performs well, the fund cannot create new shares. If, on the other hand, the fund performs poorly, LPs cannot usually redeem their money back or sell their stakes. This feature of PE funds makes them illiquid, but also creates the benefit of more stable fund structure compared to public equity. VC compensation usually has two parts: fixed fees and incentive fees. Fixed fees, as the name suggests, are pre-specified and do not depend on performance. They are akin to a management fee and are quoted as a fraction (usually 2 per cent) of the committed capital annually. Incentive fees are similar to carry and are specified as a fraction (typically 20 per cent) of any profit made above some promised return (hurdle rate). Compared to GP’s contribution, these are big numbers. Let us illustrate the compensation to LPs and GPs with a simple example. Example. VC compensation Suppose you are the GP of a VC. You open a fund with 1 per cent contribution of $1M (as GP). LPs contribute $99M. Ten years later, you manage to increase the fund value by $100M. Assume 2 per cent annual fixed fees and 20 per cent carry. What are the payoffs to GP and LP? The payoff to you as a GP consists of three components. First, since you hold 1 per cent of the fund (as you contributed $1M out of the original $100M), now you get 1 per cent of the new value of the fund: $200M. Second, you get the fixed fees of 2 per cent for each of the 10 years. Third, you are entitled to the carry which is 20 per cent of the fund profits. All in all, you get: 1%*(200M) (stake in the fund) + 2%*100M*10 (fixed fees) + 20%*(200M – 99M – 2M – 20M) (carry) = 37.8M The payoff to LPs is their original stake plus the rest of the profits: 99M + 80% * (200M – 99M – 2M – 20M) = 162.2M Note the huge return to the GP: $37.8M on $1M investment. This is due to the effective leverage taken on by the LP fund structure. 84 Chapter 6: Equity financing Finally, let us consider how VCs exit the portfolio of firms. There are two ways: M&A and IPO. In M&A, the company is acquired by another (potentially bigger) company. For example, recall the 2014 acquisition of WhatsApp by Facebook. In an IPO, a company’s equity becomes available to the general public for the first time. We will discuss this in detail in the next section. Activities You founded your own IT firm five years ago. Initially you invested $2 million of your own money and in return you received 20 million shares in the company. Last year you sold 10 million shares of stock to angel investors. Now you decide to obtain funding from a VC which would invest $50 million and would receive 20 million newly issued shares in return. What is the post-money valuation of your IT firm? Select one: a. $52 million b. $125 million c. $50 million d. $100 million Initial public offerings and seasoned equity offerings In this section, we study IPOs and SEOs. An IPO (initial public offering) is a first sale of a company’s equity to the general public, i.e. the company goes from being private to public. A SEO (seasoned equity offerings) is a sale of securities by a firm that is already publicly traded. Both of these operations take place at the primary market (firms sell to investors). This is different to the secondary market offerings, unrelated to the company (investors sell to investors). Why would a company go public? There are certain benefits of doing so. First, the company attracts funds for investment. By selling shares to new investors, the firm can raise money for new projects. Second, IPO helps to diversify the initial set of investors. Founders can cash out by selling their shares and use the money for other ventures. However, current equity holders usually sell a fraction of their shares, but not a large fraction. Why don’t they sell everything? Let us think about it. If the original owner sells all his shares in an IPO, this is usually a bad sign about the quality of the firm. Moreover, if the owner dumps all their shares, they would have fewer incentives to work hard for the company as they would no longer be compensated by an increase in the share price. The third reason why firms go public is because IPOs provide an exit strategy for VCs and other investors. Founders of the company would rather have dispersed shareholders and want VCs and banks out (recall the free rider problem: with many small shareholders, nobody has the incentive to monitor the entrepreneur). VCs and other early investors might also want to cash out. Typically, as we mentioned before, they have a five-to-10-year timeframe so might want to realise returns and move on. An IPO gives them the possibility to cash-in profits and go to the next start-up. There are also certain costs of going public. First, there are monetary costs. Among these, administrative costs account for two to10 per cent. Usually, the bigger the IPO, the lower the fraction of administrative costs – there are big economies of scale in IPOs. Furthermore, following the IPO, it is expensive for the firm to comply with regulatory filing requirements after becoming a publicly traded company. The firm has to hire new employees to prepare and to handle these reports, which costs money. Underwriting 85 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance costs are usually in the range of seven to 11 per cent. This is the fee that investment bankers (usually big reputable banks) charge for their services. They agree to buy the shares from the company and to place them to the general public. However, the most dramatic monetary cost is the IPO underpricing. A prominent feature of almost all IPOs is that the IPO price is typically lower than the day one closing price. This is a cost to existing shareholders as they could have sold the shares at a higher price than the IPO price. Second, there are disclosure requirements. Public companies are legally obliged to file honest reports. This information is publicly available, and can be used by the company’s competitors. Thus, disclosure requirements may make public firms more vulnerable to competitors. Lastly, companies that go public lose freedom as there is now oversight by the regulator. A prominent feature of most US IPOs is the seven per cent underwriting fee puzzle (see Figure 6.2). As we see, after 1988, 7 per cent is the predominant underwriting fee for most IPOs in the USA. 100.0% 90.0% 80.0% Percentage of IPOs 70.0% 60.0% Below 7% 7% 50.0% Above 7% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% 0.0% 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 Year Figure 6.2: The seven per cent underwriting fee puzzle. Let us next perform a case study on flows of cash during an IPO. Through this case, we will see a full-blown example of direct and indirect IPO costs. We will analyse who gets what and who wins and who loses (bears the costs) of a potential underpricing. Example. IPO: flow of cash Suppose you have a company and are planning to go public. Before the IPO, there are 34M shares outstanding and the firm is valued at $1.9805B. The value per share before the IPO is thus $1.9805B/34M shares = $58.25/ share. Suppose you want to raise $130.2M net equity for investment. The direct issuance cost is approximately $9.8M or 7% of gross proceeds. a. What is the post-issue stock price (Pnew) and how many shares should be issued? How much equity did the original stockholders give up? What is the value of the founders’ shares after the IPO? What is the value of (new) investors’ shares after the IPO? 86 Chapter 6: Equity financing b. Suppose the issue is underpriced at $28/share. How much equity was sold? How much did existing shareholders give away? c. The total amount of cash we need to raise is the sum of the new net equity and the issuance costs. Since the net equity is $130.2M and the direct costs are $9.8M, we get: Pnew * [N shares] = $130.2M + $9.8M = $140M The market value of the company after the IPO will be the product of a new number of shares and the new share price. As we had 34M shares before the IPO, and we issue N new shares, the total number of shares after the IPO will be $34M + N: [(34,000,000 + N)shares]* Pnew = $1.9805B + $130.2M Solving this, we get Pnew = $57.96/share and N = 2,415,385 shares. Hence, the firm has to issue 2,415,385 new shares, and the price will drop from $58.25 to $57.96. Original stockholders gave up 2,415,385 /(2,415,385 + 34,000,000) = 6.63% of the value of the firm (before they had 100 per cent of all the stocks: 34M out of 34M, now they hold a lower fraction: 34M out of 34M+2.415385M). The value of founders’ shares after the IPO is the product of the number of shares they have and the new share price: This is exactly the same as their original wealth less the direct financing costs: . The value of (new) investors’ shares after the IPO is the product of the number of shares they acquired and the new share price $57.96 * 2,415,385 shares = $140M Bottom line: As long as the issue is fairly priced, existing shareholders only lose issuing costs ($9.8M in this case). d. As the share price is $28 and we still have to attract the same amount of money, we issue shares. Since there were 34M shares originally, the total number of new shares will be 5M+34M=39M. Hence, we issue 5/(5+34) = 12.82% of the new company. The amount of money that existing shareholders give away is the product of the number of newly issued shares and the loss on each share (since they sold the shares at a much lower price than the fair value): Shares issued* (True stock value preIPO – IPO price) = 5,000,000*(58.25– 28) = $151.25M Thus, the underpricing costs of $151.25M are much higher than the direct costs of $9.8M. This example illustrates that the underpricing costs can be a very substantial part of the total IPO costs faced by existing shareholders. We will elaborate more on this in the next section when we consider IPO underpricing and winner’s curse. Next, we turn to a SEO. Remember, a SEO is when an already public company decides to issue additional shares. In contrast with IPOs, SEOs are used by already public companies. Compared to secondary market offerings, SEOs take place on the primary market as it is the firm who sells to investors. There are three main ways to issue seasoned equity: general cash offer private placement rights issue. General cash offer is a sale of securities open to all investors. In contrast, private placement, as the name suggests, is a sale of 87 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance securities to a limited number of investors without a public offering. Lastly, rights issue is an issue of securities offered only to current stockholders. It is usually quoted in terms of ‘X for Y shares’. This type of rights offer means that for every Y shares you own, you have the option to buy X more shares from the company. For example, 4 for 17 rights issue means that for every 17 shares that you own, you have the right (but not the obligation) to buy 4 in addition. Since rights issues effectively create new shares, they increase the total number of shares and thus may entail dilution effect to existing shareholders. Hence, one should consider the dilution effect when evaluating the value of rights. Let us elaborate with an example that illustrates how to calculate the value of a rights issue and the potential effects for the share price. Example. Rights issue Suppose we need to raise €1.28billion of new equity. The market price is €60 per share. We decide to raise the additional funds via a 4 for 17 rights offer at €41 per share. If we assume 100 per cent subscription, what is the value of each right? To answer this question, first we have to calculate the value of the right. It is easy to think of the rights issue as an option that gives you the right to buy shares of the company at a discounted price. We would exercise this option only when the issue price is below the market price. The value of this option is then the true value of the stock less the strike price (akin to a payoff of in-the-money call option). Value of right = true value of stock – strike price Let us calculate the value of the stock after the rights issue. We can obtain it by dividing the market value of the company by the new number of shares after the issue. The current market value of the firm (suppose only 17 shares outstanding for simplicity) is 17 × €60 = €1,020. The total number of shares will increase to 17 + 4 = 21 if everyone subscribes for the rights issue (recall that for every 17 shares existing, there are four newly created). The amount of funds after the issue is the market value plus funds attracted from investors of the rights issue. Since we sell 4 shares at the price of 41, this is 1,020 + (4 × 41) = €1,184. Finally, the new share price is 1,184/21 = €56.38 and the value of a right, calculated using the above formula is: 56.38 – 41 = €15.38. In general, the formula for the value of right is: N , Value of right = (Current Price – Issue price) ∗ N +1 where N is the number of shares per right. The equation takes into account both the price discount and the dilution. Let us check for the example above: €15.38 = (60 − 41) ∗ 88 , where N=17/4 +1 Chapter 6: Equity financing Activities Big Burger Corporation has 1 million shares outstanding. It wishes to issue 500,000 new shares using rights issue. The current stock price is $500 and the subscription price is $470/share. What is the value of a right?. Select one: a. $25/right b. $20/right c. $4/right d. $50/right IPO underpricing and winner’s curse Recall the IPO: flow of cash example from the previous section. As we saw there, underpricing can be a substantial part of the IPO costs. This section will elaborate more on this. (P − P ) In practice, IPO underpricing is the day 1 return of the stock: 1 0 P0 Why? Because it measures the costs to existing shareholders from dilution and from selling shares too cheaply. If the day 1 return is positive, existing shareholders lost money from selling their shares to the new investors at a lower price. Empirically, the day 1 return of an IPO is 16 per cent on average. This is underpricing: firms could have sold the shares for 16 per cent more. These returns are risky though – they vary widely by year (1960–1987). The worst year was 1973 when IPOs returned –18% (105 issues). The best year was 1968 when the return was +56% (368 issues). You might think 16 per cent is a small number, but once we convert it into actual money left on the table by firms going public, the figures become gigantic. VISA is the company with the largest IPO underpricing costs so far. Shareholders of VISA have left $5.075B on the table on the first day of trading! With $406M shares offered at an IPO price of $44, the closing day 1 price was $56.50. Underpricing varies also with uncertainty about the stock’s value. Larger firms are usually underpriced less. Based on data from Ritter’s website (https://site.warrington.ufl.edu/ritter/ipo-data/) and Loughran, Ritter and Rydqvist (1994)1, firms with sales less than $1M had initial excess returns of 31 per cent on an IPO. Firms with sales exceeding $25M had initial excess returns of only 5 per cent. Underpricing is smaller for older firms as they have longer track record. Moreover, IPO underpricing is an international phenomenon. Underpricing occurs in almost every country with IPOs and, again, smaller issues are underpriced more than bigger issues. (see Figure 6.3). One interesting observation is that the maturity of countries’ equity market does not explain the magnitude of the initial underpricing. For example, developed countries such as Canada, USA, the UK and Japan have well-established equity markets, but these markets feature dramatically different sizes of IPO underpricing. On the other hand, less developed equity markets, such as the ones in Russia, Iran and China, exhibit underpricing with similar magnitude and dispersion. 1 Loughran, T., J.R. Ritter, and K. Rydqvist ‘Initial public offerings: international insights’, Pacific Basin Finance Journal 3 1994, pp.139–40. Long-run returns of IPO firms go in the opposite direction: shares of firm that went public perform poorly in the long run after three years. From a sample of 1,500 IPO’s the three-year returns were 34 per cent, compared with a 62 per cent return on a portfolio of small stocks in similar 89 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance industries. Thus, holding shares of firms that recently went public, for a long period after the IPO, proofs to be a bad investing strategy. Russia Argentina Austria Canada Denmark Chile Norway Netherlands France Turkey Spain Portugal Nigeria Belgium Israel Hong Kong Mexico UK Italy USA Finland S. Africa New Zealand Philippines Iran Australia Poland Cyprus Ireland Germany Indonesia Sweden Singapore Switzerland Sri Lanka Brazil Bulgaria Thailand Taiwan Japan Greece Korea Malaysia India China Small underpricing Medium underpricing High underpricing 0 20 40 60 80 100 Figure 6.3: IPO underpricing – international evidence. Why are IPOs underpriced? Why do private firms leave money on the table when they go public? There are several potential explanations: • Underwriter price supports. Underwriters can support the price of an IPO by buying shares at the IPO price or lower. This can lead to underpricing because, to minimise the costs and to decrease the probability of potential price support transactions, underwriters might prefer lower IPO price. • Benefit the underwriter. Lower IPO price favors the clients of the underwriters – they can buy at the offer price and realise gains on the first day of trading. This might be beneficial for the reputation of the underwriter and clients might be more willing to subscribe to further IPOs of the same underwriter. • Risk averse owners. The original owners might perceive the IPO as a once-in-a-lifetime very positive NPV project where they can become rich immediately. Owners may be afraid that too high a price could cause the IPO to fail or to attract fewer investors; hence the offered price is set lower. • Information asymmetry (winner’s curse). There are two types of investors: informed (they know for sure whether the firm is bad or good) and uninformed (they have no idea whether the firm is good or bad). Informed investors stay away from bad deals. Uninformed investors get 100 per cent of bad IPOs but only a fraction in good IPOs. To break even, uninformed investors need a discount on the fair price. The winner’s curse problem is one of the most prevalent explanations for the IPO underpricing. Let us elaborate more on this story. The winner’s curse problem is typical in auctions: when bidders have different private 90 120 140 Chapter 6: Equity financing information, the winner of the auction tends to overpay for the item. How does this relate to an IPO? Analogously, in an IPO, uninformed investors tend to overpay for bad firms. To the contrary, informed investors participate in an IPO only if the firm is good. Now, assume you are uninformed investor and your average evaluations are correct. If you bid the average estimates in an IPO, and the IPO is a good deal, you get small (or no) allocation in the issue because informed investors also participate. However, when the IPO is bad, informed investors withdraw and you are the only buyer. You end up with a big allocation in a bad firm, for which you paid a higher price than the fair one (since the average between a good and a bad deal is larger than a bad deal). Thus, on average, when you win a lot of allocation, it means it is a bad IPO – winner’s curse problem. Moreover, your expected return is negative. Hence, in order to break even, you bid at a discount which means that the day 1 closing price should be higher than the IPO price. This leads to IPO underpricing. In some sense, the IPO underpricing is a form of a ‘bribe’ to attract the uninformed investors to the offering. Let us consider an example which shows us why uninformed investors need a lower-than fair price at the IPO to break even. Example. IPO underpricing Suppose you want to participate in an IPO but you don’t know whether it is a good or a bad deal – you are uninformed. You think that the shares are equally likely to go to $0 (bad deal) or to $2 (bad deal) after the IPO. There is also an informed trader who knows the outcome. There are two shares available to subscribe. Both you and the informed can choose to buy the new shares. If both of you choose to buy, each gets one share. If only you choose to buy, you get two shares. Are you willing to buy at the average price of $1? No! Why? Let us think. Consider the strategy of the informed investor and the allocation outcome. If the IPO is bad, the informed investor withdraws and we ‘win’ all of the shares. The ultimate payoff will be $0 and our total payoff is $–2 (since we paid $1 for 2 shares worth nothing). If the IPO is good, both you and the informed investor get 1 share worth $2. Thus, the payoff to you is: 0.5*(–1 + 2) + 0.5*(–2 + 0) = $–0.5 <$0 (you get $0 if you do not participate in the IPO). This is the winner’s curse issue: you cannot break even if you bid for the shares. Hence, the IPO price should be lower than $1 to attract you which explains the IPO underpricing. Consider yet another example which shows that the expected day 1 return on an IPO has to be positive in an environment with both bad and good IPO deals. Example. Winner’s curse MM Enterprises is going public with an offer of 1,000 shares at $1/ share. With 40 per cent chance, MM Enterprises will turn out to be a bad company which we will refer to as a ‘Dog’ and with 60 per cent chance it will be good, which we will call a ‘Jewel’. Assume ‘Dogs’ have an initial return of –20%. There is no discounting and everyone is risk neutral. There exist both informed (very small group for any given issue) and uninformed investors. Informed investors know whether or not MM is a dog or a jewel, and subscribe only to jewels. Informed investors have capacity to buy 500 shares. Uninformed investors subscribe to all issues. In the event of oversubscription, shares are rationed (Table 6.3). 91 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Dog (40% Probability) Jewel (60% Probability) Informed 0 500 Uninformed 1,000 500 Table 6.3 Shares rationing. We need participation by uniformed investors; otherwise the IPO will not go through. They must earn an average 1–day return of 0 per cent. What is the required return from a ‘Jewel’ for uniformed investors to participate in the IPO? Assume is the day 1 return from ‘Jewel’. Then the expected day 1 return for an uninformed investor is: .4($1000)(1 – .20) + .6(500)(1 + Rj) + .6(500)(1 + 0) = 1000 (1 + 0) The first term on the left-hand side of the equation above is the return on allocated shares in a bad IPO, the second the return on allocated shares in a good IPO, and the last the return on unused cash. The right-hand side is the return from not participating in the IPO. Solving yields . What is the expected return on the IPO then? E(RIPO) = .4*(–20%) + .6*(26.67%) = 8% This is the average day 1 return (underpricing)! A reminder of your learning outcomes At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain venture capital and equity issuance in the public market • perform valuation with multiple financing rounds • explain the calculate ownership structure in initial public offerings and seasoned equity offerings • explain and evaluate the winners’ curse problem. Key terms Initial public offerings IPO underpricing Private equity Rights offerings Seasoned equity offerings Staged financing Venture capital Winner’s curse problem 92 Chapter 6: Equity financing Sample examination questions 1. Swipechat recently completed its IPO. The stock was offered at a price of $1.40 per share. On the first day of trading, the stock closed at $1.90 per share. a. What was the initial return on Swipechat? b. Who benefited from this underpricing? c. Who lost, and why? 2. In 2017 the Duckdonalds Corporation made a rights issue at $50 a share of one new share for every four shares held. There were 10 million shares outstanding before this issue and the share price was $60. For Parts (a) - (c) assume that all rights were exercised. a. What was the total amount of new money raised? b. What was the prospective stock price after the issue? c. What was the value of the right to buy one new share? d. How far could the stock price decrease after the issue before shareholders would be unwilling to take up their rights? e. Assume that the rights issue is at $40 rather than $50 per share. How many new shares would it have needed to sell to raise the same amount of money? How do your answers to (c) and (d) change? Are the shareholders any better or worse off with the $40 exercise price? 3. Two years ago, you founded Pineapple Computers, Inc., a retailer specialising in the sale of IT equipment. So far your company has gone through three funding rounds: Round Date Investor Shares Issued Share Price ($) Series A Feb 2011 You 50,000 10 Series B Aug 2012 Angels 100,000 20 Series C Sept 2013 Venture Capital 200,000 35 It is 2015 and you need to raise additional funding to expand your business. You have decided to take your firm public through an IPO. You would like to issue an additional 650,000 shares at this IPO. If your firm successfully completes its IPO, the 2015 net income will be $750,000. a. Your investment banker advises you that the prices of other recent IPOs have been set such that the P/E ratios based on 2015 forecasted earnings average 20.0. Assuming that your IPO is set at a price that implies a similar multiple, what will your IPO price per share be? b. What percentage of the firm will you own after the IPO? 93 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Notes 94 Chapter 7: Dividend policy Chapter 7: Dividend policy Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to analyse and explain the choices of dividend policies made by firms’ managers. With this aim in mind, we first introduce a stylised model in which dividend policy is irrelevant (Modigliani–Miller). We then relax some of the assumptions made in this stylised model in order to explain empirical evidence on firms’ dividend policies. Learning objectives By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • show that dividend policy (and share repurchases) are irrelevant to firm valuation under the Modigliani–Miller assumptions • discuss the stylised facts of dividend policy provided by Lintner • present the clientele model of dividends • discuss the effects of asymmetric information and agency costs on dividend behaviour. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapter 17 (Payout Policy). Further reading Allen, F. and R. Michaely ‘Dividend Policy’ in Jarrow, R.A., V. Maksimovic and W.T. Ziemba (eds) Handbooks in Operational Research and Management Science: Volume 9: Finance. (Amsterdam: North Holland, 1995). Bhattacharya, S. ‘Imperfect information, dividend policy, and “the bird in the hand” fallacy’, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1) 1979, pp.259–70. Blume, M., J. Crockett and I. Friend ‘Stock ownership in the United States: characteristics and trends’, Survey of Current Business 54(11) 1974, pp.16–40. Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapter 16. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 15 (How Taxes Affect Dividends and Share Repurchases) and 19 (The Information Conveyed by Financial Decisions). Healy, P. and K. Palepu ‘Earnings information conveyed by dividend initiations and omissions’, Journal of Financial Economics 21(2) 1988, pp.149–76. Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976, pp.305–60. Lintner, J. ‘Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained earnings and taxes’, American Economic Review 46(2) 1956, pp.97–113. Myers, S. ‘Determinants of corporate borrowing’, Journal of Financial Economics 5(2) 1977, pp.147–75. Ross, S. ‘The determination of financial structure: the incentive signalling approach’, Bell Journal of Economics 8(1) 1977, pp.23–40. 95 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Overview The dividend is a cash payment (usually made on an annual or semiannual basis) to the owners of corporate equity and is the basic financial inducement for individuals to hold shares. In Chapter 1, when analysing discounted cash-flow techniques, we demonstrated how to price an equity share, given knowledge of the future dividend stream that would accrue to the share. Such an analysis might be undertaken by an investor in order to assess the ‘value’ of an equity share. The current chapter analyses dividends from the opposite perspective, that of the manager of a corporation who must decide on the level of dividends to pay out. In a similar vein to the analysis of capital structure in Chapters 5 and 6, the fundamental question we wish to answer is: what dividend policy is optimal for management in that its adoption results in maximum firm value? How to return capital to equity holders? There are two main ways in which companies return money to equity holders: dividends and share repurchases. Let us focus first on dividends. There are two types of dividends: cash dividends and stock dividends. In the first type, a firm pays cash to shareholders: for example, for every share they have, shareholders receive $1 of cash paid from the company’s account. If the stock price is $100 in that case, the dividend yield is 1 per cent. Cash dividends are paid either regularly (quarterly, (semi-)annually), or as a one-time payout – special cash dividends. Stock dividends, on the other hand, do not involve any actual cash flows from the company to the investors. In a stock dividend, the firm just creates new shares and distributes them among existing shareholders. For example, for every 100 shares an investor has, she receives one new share. Stock dividends are hardly a ‘payout’, as the company does not pay actual money from its account to equity holders. This type of dividend is similar to a stock split, but with a smaller order of magnitude. In the previous example, every 100 shares receive one new share, whereas in a typical stock split, much more shares are created. For example, in a twofor-one split every 100 shares receive 100 new shares. Typically, when firms announce a stock dividend, the share price drops. Think about the following analogy of a one per cent stock dividend: suppose you have your money split into 100 wallets. Now you decide to split the same amount of money in 101 wallets. The total sum of money in all wallets is the same but the amount of money in each of the 101 wallets is lower than the amount of money in each of the 100 wallets before. Analogously, the share price after the stock dividend (101 shares outstanding) is lower than the price before the dividend (100 shares outstanding). Now let us talk about the timing of dividend payments. There are several important dates in a typical dividend payment. First, the announcement date is the date when the firm states the dividend amount. In the announcement, usually, firms also specify the payment date and the record date. The payment date is the day on which dividends are actually paid. The record date is the date on which the firm takes a snapshot of all investors who own shares of the company: it is only these investors who will receive the dividend. For example, suppose at t=0 the firm announces a dividend payment taking place at t=7 with a record date at t=5. Suppose that it takes two days to settle a buy-sell transaction of a firm’s shares. If you 96 Chapter 7: Dividend policy buy a share of the company any time before t=3, you will be eligible for a dividend as at t=5 the transaction will be settled and you will be holding shares in the company. However, if you buy the share at, say, t=4, you will not receive the dividend as you will only become an official shareholder at t=4+2=6, which is after the record date. In relation to this, the first day the stock trades without the dividend, is called the ex-dividend date (t=4 in our example). The day before the ex-dividend day, is called the cumdividend date (t=3 in our example). Figure 7.1 illustrates the timeline of a typical dividend payment. If you buy the share on or after the ex-dividend date, you will not receive the declared dividend. If you buy the share on or before the cum-dividend date, you will receive the dividend. Figure 7.1: Timeline of a dividend. Now let us talk about the second way firms distribute capital to equity holders: share repurchases. In a share repurchase, firms use cash to buy back stocks. The most popular way is via open market repurchases: firms buy shares on the public market anonymously and then cancel these shares. In a share repurchase, firms may sometimes treat different shareholders heterogeneously: for example, they can buy most of the shares from one or a small group of investors, and not buy any shares from other investors. Open market repurchases provide some tax flexibility: investors can delay the tax by not selling the shares, for example. In contrast, with a dividend payment, shareholders cannot avoid the tax because, as soon as the dividend is paid, they are obliged to pay the tax. Lastly, these repurchases are usually spread over time: they can last up to three years. The next way to do a share repurchase is a tender offer. In this operation, the firm offers to buy a certain number of shares at a specified price. For example, it offers to buy 1 million shares at the price of $1. Then, shareholders can choose whether to participate by subscribing for the offer or not. If there are enough subscriptions, the offer goes through. If there are more shares in the subscription, say, 2 million, the company can either randomly pick 1 million from these, or ration the shares on a pro-rata basis: each investor sells 50 per cent of the shares they initially intended to sell as part of the tender offer. Modigliani–Miller meets dividends In Chapter 5 we argued that, under a given set of assumptions, firm value is independent of capital structure (i.e. the MM theorem was valid). These assumptions include the following: • frictionless markets (no taxes or transaction costs) • symmetric information 97 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance • no agency costs • investment outcomes independent of financing decisions. The assumptions that give us MM1 actually yield a far more powerful result than just the irrelevancy of debt policy. They imply that the entire financial policy followed by a firm is irrelevant for its valuation; all that matters is the firm’s portfolio of investment projects. Hence, capital structure, dividend policy and risk management activities (among other things) are all ineffectual in altering firm value. We have restated the theorem and application of its logic to dividend policy, below. Consider a firm that has fixed its investment policy. In each period, it is left with a net cash flow, which is simply the difference between operating income and investment costs. A straightforward corporate dividend policy would just be to pay out this net cash flow to the holders of equity. However, consider a firm that desires to pay a dividend in excess of its net cash flow. In order to do this, the firm can raise funds by issuing new equity. Alternatively, the firm could borrow money which, assuming perfect capital markets, is a transaction with NPV of zero. Conversely, a firm wishing to pay a smaller dividend might spend the balance of its net cash flow on repurchasing equity. The key idea here is that a firm can choose whatever payout policy it desires, funding the policy through share issues/repurchases; hence, dividend policy is irrelevant. From the individual investor’s point of view we can show that dividend policy is irrelevant too. To do this we can use a similar argument to that employed in our argument that shareholders are indifferent to capital structure changes; shareholders are indifferent to dividend policy as, through appropriate purchases or sales of shares, they can replicate any dividend policy they wish. Hence, investors will not value a firm paying a particular dividend policy different to any other firm such that firm value does not depend on dividends. We will pick up this theme in the following section. Prices, dividends and share repurchases It is straightforward to show that investors are indifferent to cash received through dividends or share repurchases. To see this, consider an all-equity firm, which has a current market value of $100,000. There are 2,000 shares outstanding, such that the current share price is $50. The firm is due to pay a $10 per share dividend tomorrow. In this scenario (i.e. just before the payment of a dividend) the current share price of $50 is called the cum-dividend share price. First, let’s analyse what would happen to the share price after dividend payment. The total dividend payment is $10*2,000 = $20,000. Hence, after a dividend payment, the total firm value will be $100,000 – $20,000 = $80,000. As there are still 2,000 shares outstanding, the share price after dividend payment is $80,000/2,000 = $40. This is called the ex-dividend share price. Note the obvious result that the sum of dividend paid and exdividend share price is equal to the cum-dividend share price ($80,000 + $20,000 = $100,000). Activity A firm has current share price of £2.50 and will pay a £0.15 per share dividend tomorrow. What is the share price immediately after dividend payment? 98 Chapter 7: Dividend policy Consider the cash position of an individual who originally held five shares in our firm. The value of their shareholding was originally $250. After the dividend payment, they have cash of $50, and the value of their shareholding is $200. Hence, the dividend has just altered the composition of their wealth rather than changing its dollar amount. What happens if, instead, the firm decides to use the cash it had originally earmarked for dividend payment for a share repurchase instead? As mentioned above, the total dividend amount was $20,000. As the original share price was $50, this implies that the firm can repurchase $20,000/$50 = 400 shares. As a result, after the share repurchase, there are 1,600 shares outstanding, and the firm is again worth $80,000 in total. Therefore, the post-share repurchase share price must be $80,000/1,600 = $50. Note that a share repurchase (at a fair price) does not alter share prices. Again, consider the position of our individual who originally owned five shares. The firm repurchases 400 shares, which is one-fifth of all equity. Now, assume that one share of this individual’s holding of five is repurchased. The repurchase thus gives them $50 and, after the repurchase, their four remaining shares are worth $200 in all. As a result, in this case also, their $250 invested in equity has been changed into $50 of cash and $200 still in equity. This is identical to the case where dividends were paid. Thus, the individual is indifferent between dividends and share repurchases. The manner in which the firm chooses to distribute cash does not matter to them and, as a result, they will not discriminate (in value terms) between stocks that do and do not pay dividends. Dividend policy: stylised facts Our prior discussion led to the conclusion that dividend policy is irrelevant (i.e. the choice of policy doesn’t affect firm value). However, certain formal and casual empirical observations point in the opposite direction. In this section we will provide a brief and selective review of such empirical research on dividend policy. Perhaps the most famous set of results on actual dividend policy was compiled and presented by John Lintner (1958). Lintner interviewed the management of a sample of US corporations in order to determine what lay behind their dividend-setting decisions. His research led to the four following stylised facts. 1. Managers seem to have a target dividend payout level. 2. This payout level is determined as a proportion of long-run (i.e. sustainable) earnings of the firm. 3. Managers are more concerned with changes in dividends rather than the actual level of dividends. 4. Managers prefer not to make dividend changes that might need to be reversed (e.g. cutting dividends after having raised them in the previous period). As the second fact implies, it is not current but long-run earnings that matter in setting dividends such that dividends can be seen to be smoothed relative to earnings. These observations led Lintner to develop the characterisation of dividend behaviour that is given in equation 7.1. It is a simple partial adjustment model: ΔDt = λ(αEPSt – Dt–1), 0 < α < 1, 0 < λ < 1 (7.1) 99 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance where Dt is the time t dividend per share, EPSt is earnings per share at t, α is the target payout ratio, and λ is the parameter governing the degree of dividend smoothing. In line with facts 1 and 2, equation 7.1 embodies a target payout, which is a simple proportion of earnings. Also, the change in dividends appears on the left-hand side of 7.1 in line with fact 3. Note that, if λ was equal to one, then the dividend change at time t would always ensure that dividends were at precisely their target level (i.e. we would have Dt = α EPSt). However, for values of λ less than one, dividends change towards their target level gradually. This reflects the smoothing of dividends that Lintner’s stylised facts indicate. The other major source of empirical observations on the effects of dividend policy has been the event study literature, which has also emphasised the vast importance of changes in dividends. A wide range of studies for equity from many different countries has demonstrated that dividend cuts lead to drops in stock price on average, whereas dividend increases on average lead to stock price rises.1 The interested reader can consult Healy and Palepu (1988), among other writers. Clearly then, putting together the empirical evidence from interviews and event studies yields an impressive case for the relevance of dividend policy. The results of Lintner (1956) indicate that corporate managers do not perceive dividend policy as irrelevant. Rather, they seem to follow similar plans in their payout policy. Further, the event study evidence tells us that the market interprets unexpected dividend increases as good news for a stock, whereas unexpected dividend cuts are regarded as bad news. 1 No change in dividends is (as one might expect) associated with little or no effect on stock prices on average. Hence, we have a case for arguing that the dividend version of the MM theorem is invalid. However, we have not yet come up with reasons for why it is invalid. In the following two sections we will explore three sets of reasons (similar to those put forward to explain the relevancy of capital structure): namely, the existence of taxation, asymmetric information and agency costs. Taxation and clientele theory An obvious omission from our story of dividend policy irrelevancy is taxation. Previously we argued that, with no taxes, share-holders should be indifferent between income in the form of dividends or income from capital gains. This would still be true if dividends and capital gains were taxed symmetrically, that is both the tax rate and the timing of taxes are the same. However, it is generally true that the dividend payments accruing to individuals are taxed more heavily than capital gains. We would therefore expect individuals to prefer income in the form of capital gains. Corporations, on the other hand, are taxed very favourably on dividend income on the shares of other firms that they hold. Corporations, therefore, should prefer dividend income to capital gains income. Finally, some institutions pay no taxes whatsoever. These institutions will not care whether income is earned as either dividends or capital gains. The preceding observations on taxes lay the foundations for the clientele theory of dividends. The notion behind this theory is straightforward. Given the three groups above, we might expect some stocks to pay high dividends (with these stocks held by corporations), some stocks to pay medium dividend levels (and these are held by tax-exempt institutions) and finally certain firms to pay low dividends (and their shares are held by individuals). Each type of stock (classified according to dividend levels) caters to its own ‘clientele’ of investor. A numerical example will yield further insights.2 100 This example is based on that given in Allen and Michaely (1995). 2 Chapter 7: Dividend policy Assume an economy populated by risk-neutral agents. Individuals pay a tax rate of 50 per cent on dividend income and 20 per cent on capital gains. Corporations pay tax at rate 10 per cent on dividend income and 35 per cent on capital gains. Three types of stock exist in the economy: high, medium and low payout stocks. Each stock has earnings per share of 100. Payout policies, stock prices and after-tax payoffs are given in Table 7.1. Payout policy High Medium Low 100 50 0 0 50 100 Individuals 50 65 80 Corporations 90 77.5 65 Institutions 100 100 100 1,000 1,000 1,000 Dividend Capital gain After tax payoffs Equilibrium price Table 7.1 Clearly, given the after-tax payoffs to each group, individuals will hold low payout stocks, corporations will hold high payout stocks, and institutions are indifferent. Assume that in equilibrium the total holdings of each group are as given in Table 7.2. Payout policy High Medium Low 0 0 320m Corporations 110m 0 0 Institutions 500m 730m 220m Total 610m 730m 540m Individuals Table 7.2 Note that in Table 7.1 we displayed the equilibrium price of each equity share as 1,000. Why is this the case? To see this, assume that the price of low payout stock is 1,050, whereas the price of all other stock is 1,000. This would imply that high and medium dividend level firms have an incentive to switch to low dividend policies (to take advantage of the high share prices). Such actions would increase the supply of low dividend stocks and hence depress their price. A reinforcing effect comes from the demand side. The return that individuals get from holding low payout stock is 80/1,050 = 7.62%. This exceeds the returns they would gain from holding medium and high payout stocks (which are 6.5 per cent and 5 per cent respectively), and hence individuals continue to demand low dividend stocks. Institutions, on the other hand, only get a return of 9.52 per cent from holding low payout stock (100/1,050 = 9.52 per cent), whereas they get a return of 10 per cent on other types of equity. Thus, institutions rationally sell their low dividend equity. This further depresses the price. It is only when the price of low dividend stock is 1,000 that equilibrium is reached. The clientele model leads to the same main result as MM. Firm values (or stock prices) are unaffected by dividend policy. There are obviously underlying differences to these theories though. For example, the clientele theory implies that investors in high tax brackets should hold portfolios with low dividend yields and vice versa.3 3 The dividend yield on a stock is the ratio of dividend payment to stock price. Evidence for this prediction is given in Blume, Crockett and Friend (1974). 101 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Let us elaborate more on the timing of dividend and the tax deferral of capital gain. Suppose a company has a current share price of 100 and has an additional income at 5 per cent every year. The company can choose between two dividend policies: in policy A, it pays 5 per cent dividend every year so that the share price stays constant at 100. In policy B, it does not pay any dividend, but reinvests the additional income in the firm so that the share price grows by 5 per cent per year. Suppose both dividend and capital gain tax rates are 40 per cent. As a shareholder of the company with an investment horizon of 10 years, are we indifferent between the two payout methods? No, because we can defer capital gain tax under policy B. How? Recall dividends are immediately taxable upon payment, and investors can only use after-tax dividend to reinvest. Then, the dividend on the reinvestment is again taxed in the next round of payout after it generates some new profits. However, if the capital is returned in the form of repurchase, such a repeated taxation problem would not appear. Investors are only taxed once upon the liquidation of their shares. This is the crucial difference between the two payout methods. Thus, even if the tax rates are the same, paying dividends still incurs higher tax liability. Let us see why this is the case by calculating the gain under the two different policies. If the company chooses policy A, we as shareholders receive after tax dividend of 3 = 5 * (1 – 40%) in year 1. Then, we reinvest the dividend and get 3 per cent after tax return every year. After 10 years, our proceeds are 100 * 1.0310 = 134.4. If the firm chooses policy B, we do not pay any taxes over the next 10 years as we receive zero dividends. After 10 years, we sell the stock at a price of 100 * 1.0510 = 162.9. After paying tax of 40% on the capital gain (162.9 – 100), our final proceeds are 162.9 – (162.9 – 100) * 40% = 137.7 which is higher than the gain under policy A. Asymmetric information and dividends A popular version of the asymmetric information story for the relevance of dividends is very similar to the reasoning underlying the relevance of capital structure in Ross (1977). This model argued that debt policy was relevant as, in a world where firm quality was not observable to the market, the level of debt chosen by a firm’s management signalled the quality of the firm. High-quality firms would choose high debt levels (as they could afford the interest payments without running into cash-flow problems), whereas poor firms would choose low levels of debt. Hence, debt acted as an observable signal of firm quality upon which the market would base its valuation of a firm. Exactly the same type of logic can be applied to dividend policy. If we again assume that corporate managers’ objective function is increasing in expected firm value but decreasing in expected bankruptcy costs then, in a world where firm quality is not observable to outsiders, dividend policy can be used as a signal. High-quality firms (i.e. firms with large average cash flows) can afford to pay large dividends, as they worry less about bankruptcy than low-quality firms. The latter pay low dividends to avoid bankruptcy. Interpretation of such signals by investors means that firms paying high dividends are valued more highly in the market than those paying low amounts. In empirical terms, the prior argument would then imply a positive relationship between dividend levels and firm value. Further, we might also expect that cuts in dividends would result in share price reductions, as this might be interpreted as a signal of reductions in a firm’s quality. Conversely, dividend increases should correlate with share price rises. Such 102 Chapter 7: Dividend policy empirical predictions fit quite nicely with those empirical results discussed earlier in the chapter. Agency costs and dividends Consider a situation where the ownership and control of corporations are separated. Organisations are assumed to be controlled by managers, who can only be imperfectly monitored by owners/shareholders and, as a result, there is scope for managers to behave opportunistically. In such situations, our analysis of the results of Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Myers (1977) indicated that capital structure changes may alter firm value, such that MM1 was violated. The same situation may imply that dividend policy affects firm value. Here, we give only the briefest treatment of this possibility. Both of the agency cost models of capital structure referenced above include situations where managers, acting in the interest of equity-holders, transfer value away from debt-holders towards those who own shares.4 Similar activities may be undertaken with dividend policy. Managers may pay out large levels of dividends (benefiting equity-holders), financing these payments by rejecting positive NPV projects or by increasing debt levels. If debt-holders do not anticipate this behaviour, the value of debt will be reduced while the value of equity increases. Note that, in both cases, ‘excessive’ dividend payments will lead to lower firm values. 4 Asset substitution and debt overhang are examples of such behaviour. An interesting feature of this argument is that it predicts that dividend increases should be reflected in higher market values for equity but lower market values for debt. This contrasts with the implications of the asymmetric information-based theories, which, as dividend increases are good news in general, predict that they should lead to increases in the values of both debt and equity. From the preceding section we know that dividend increases result in higher equity values empirically, consistent with both agency- and information-based theories. However, recent empirical evidence suggests that, at least for US firms, corporate bond prices drop when dividends are cut and don’t change significantly when dividend increases are announced. Such results would seem to indicate that theories of dividend policy based on asymmetric information are more realistic than those based on agency costs. Summary We started this chapter by arguing that, like capital structure, dividend policy should not affect firm value. Subsequent to this, however, we pointed out several sources of real world imperfection that might lead to optimal dividend policies (in the sense of firm value maximisation). Such imperfections included taxation, information asymmetries and agency costs. We also explored some of the empirical results on dividend policy. Empirical evidence shows that equity prices tend to rise after unexpected dividend increases and fall after unexpected dividend cuts (with bond prices following a similar pattern). This, we argued, seemed most supportive of dividend models based on asymmetric information. The dividend puzzle is far from resolved, however. Much research work remains to be done in the area to clarify our understanding of the fundamental determinants of corporate dividend policy. Lintner’s stylised facts and results from event studies have given us a good empirical basis 103 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance upon which to construct realistic theories of dividend behaviour, and it is precisely this task that currently confronts finance theorists. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • show that dividend policy (and share repurchases) are irrelevant to firm valuation under the Modigliani–Miller assumptions • discuss the stylised facts of dividend policy as provided by Lintner • present the clientele model of dividends • discuss the effects of asymmetric information and agency costs on dividend behaviour. Key terms agency costs asymmetric information capital structure clientele model dividend policy frictionless markets Lintner’s stylised facts Modigliani–Miller irrelevance theorem personal taxes share repurchases target dividend payout level taxes on capital gains taxes on dividends Sample examination questions 1. Describe the model of dividend policy formulated by Lintner (1956) and detail the stylised facts upon which this model is based. 2. ‘The Modigliani–Miller theorems imply that firms’ dividend policy does not affect their value in the slightest.’ What assumptions underlie this statement? Give two scenarios in which the statement is invalid. 3. For tax reasons it is cheaper to pay equity-holders through share repurchases than with dividends. Nevertheless, many firms use dividends to pay their investors. What is the signaling explanation for this? 104 Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to explain why managers of firms are engaging in mergers and acquisitions. With this aim in mind, we first introduce a stylised model in which efficient takeovers cannot possibly obtain (Grossman–Hart). We then introduce institutional mechanisms which enable takeovers to occur. Finally, we investigate whether or not mergers and acquisitions create value and provide empirical evidence on returns to shareholders of bidding and target firms. Learning objectives By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading, you should be able to: • discuss motivations for merger activity • analyse simple numerical examples of efficient takeover activity • detail the argument of Grossman­–Hart (1980) regarding the impossibility of efficient takeovers • present ways in which this analysis can be modified to permit takeovers to occur. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapter 32 (Mergers). Further reading Bradley, M., A. Desai and E. Kim ‘Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms’, Journal of Financial Economics 21(1) 1988, pp.3–40. Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2004) Chapter 18. Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapter 20 (Mergers and Acquisitions). Grossman, S. and O. Hart ‘Takeover bids, the free-rider problem and the theory of the corporation’, Bell Journal of Economics 11(1) 1980, pp.42–64. Healy, P., K. Palepu and R. Ruback ‘Does corporate performance improve after mergers?’, Journal of Financial Economics 31(2) 1992, pp.135–76. Jarrell, G., J. Brickley and J. Netter ‘The market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since 1980’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(1) 1988, pp.49–68. Jarrell, G. and A. Poulsen ‘Returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: evidence from three decades’, Financial Management 18(3) 1989, pp.12–19. Jensen, M. ‘Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers’, American Economic Review 76(2) 1986, pp.323–29. Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976, pp.305–60. Jensen, M. and R. Ruback ‘The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence’, Journal of Financial Economics 11(1–4) 1983, pp.5–50. 105 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Myers, S. and N. Majluf ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.187–221. Ravenscraft, D. and F. Scherer Mergers, selloffs, and economic efficiency. (Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1987). Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny ‘Large shareholders and corporate control’, Journal of Political Economy 94(3) 1986, pp.461–88. Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny ‘Managerial entrenchment: The case of managementspecific investment’, Journal of Financial Economics 25 1989, pp.123–39. Travlos, N. ‘Corporate takeover bids, methods of payment, and bidding firms’ stock returns’, Journal of Finance 42(4) 1987, pp.943–63. Overview The post-Second World War period has seen an unprecedented amount of corporate activity resulting in the combination of two or more firms under a single corporate banner and legal status. Such activity comes in many forms and is initiated for varying reasons. This chapter gives an introduction to the concepts underlying merger/takeover/acquisition activity and provides a basic review of the theory of takeover activity, and supplies empirical evidence on returns to takeovers. In line with the arguments presented throughout this guide, we argue that merger activity should be judged in terms of the value it delivers. Mergers should be undertaken if they are positive NPV transactions. A mathematical way of stating this is that: VXY > VX + VY, (8.1) that is, the value of the merged firm created from firms X and Y (VXY) exceeds the sum of pre-merger values of X and Y (i.e. VX + VY). Such value may come about through the exploitation of scale economies or elimination of inefficiencies. We will give a classification of merger and acquisition behaviour based on the source of value in the following section. Merger motivations Following Grinblatt and Titman (2002), we will split merger and takeover activity into three distinct sub-groups: • financial activity • strategic activity • conglomerate activity. 1. Financial mergers: these are takeovers or acquisitions that are initiated to take advantage of corporate inefficiencies that lead to the under-valuation of firms. This allows an acquiring firm to buy assets cheaply, implement strategies that increase the value of the acquired firm and then sell on the acquired assets at a profit (if so desired). Such activity yields a positive net present value. Opportunities for financial mergers are likely to come about due to managers of acquired firms following their own, rather than shareholders’, goals and hence not maximising firm value. In this way, the market for corporate control is said to exert discipline on a firm’s management.1 The merger wave of the 1980s may be thought of as largely comprised of such activity. An active market for corporate control (in the form of hostile takeovers) is therefore an important force that mitigates the problems arising from the separation of ownership and control in modern corporations. 106 This is because, if a takeover occurs, incumbent management are likely to lose their jobs. Hence, assuming management would prefer to retain their jobs, the possibility of takeover limits managerial scope for inefficiency. 1 Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers 2. Strategic mergers: financial mergers generate value through eliminating corporate inefficiency induced by bad management. Strategic mergers yield value through the taking advantage of economies of scale and scope in production, purchasing and marketing. Hence, horizontal integration activity undertaken to increase and exploit market power and to take advantage of scale economies fall into this category. Also, acquisitions that are vertically integrating may be thought of as strategic activity due to their yielding lower production costs or marketing expenses. A recent example of such activity might be the announced link-ups within the French banking sector in February 1999.2 3. Conglomerate mergers: certain mergers are clearly not motivated by scale economies and are not attempts to take advantage of corporate mismanagement. The most obvious examples of such activity are between firms in very different industries and these link-ups are known as conglomerate mergers. This type of activity was very popular in the 1960s and 1970s (although much of the conglomeration that occurred in these decades was reversed in the 1980s). Motivations for conglomerate merger are unclear. Some have stated that the element of diversification that conglomeration yields adds to value. However, given that investors can diversify their own portfolios in order to reduce risk (i.e. they don’t need firms to diversify for them), the idea that value is added for this reason is flawed. Along similar lines, some have argued that a gain from conglomeration is derived due to lower interest rates that conglomerates are charged.3 Again, however, this argument doesn’t stand up to close scrutiny. One reason why conglomeration may occur is that it allows firms with large amounts of cash (who do not want to increase dividends or repurchase equity) to profitably employ this cash in positive NPV projects. In early February 1999, BNP and Société Générale announced plans to merge. Later, Paribas entered the fray, announcing that it would take over the other two banks. 2 3 Conglomerates may be charged lower interest rates as cash-flow risk is reduced through precisely the diversification argument already mentioned. Payment method in takeover Just like we need to pay for our everyday purchases, acquiring companies need to pay owners (shareholders) of target firms in takeover and merger deals. Quite often, acquiring companies pay even more than the current market price of the target firm. This premium is the cost of takeover for the acquirer. The payment method in our daily purchases is straightforward: we pay cash to the seller in exchange for goods. The acquiring company can do the same. It can simply pay cash to the target’s shareholders who sell the company. This type of takeover is known as a cash deal. It is important to note that in such a deal the purchase price is paid out from the firm’s assets. Hence, the total firm value after the takeover should exclude the purchase price. Alternatively, instead of using cash, the acquiring company can offer new shares to compensate the target shareholders. This type of takeover is known as a stock deal. Such a deal is often structured as an exchange offer: for example, every 10 shares of the target company can be exchanged for three shares of the acquiring company. Once the exchange is complete, the target company’s shares no longer exist and the acquiring company’s shares become the only equity claim on the entire post-takeover company. It is crucial to recognise that the shares offered to target shareholders do not usually come from the current shareholders of the acquiring company. Instead, these shares are newly created claims on the post-takeover company. As we shall see in the following examples, the fair 107 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance share price is the total firm value post-takeover divided by the new total number of shares outstanding. The new number of shares is calculated as a pre-takeover number of shares plus new shares offered to the target shareholders. Note that, unlike in cash deals, stock deals typically do not involve the transfer of resource from the firm to the target shareholders. The owners of the target company merely join those of the acquiring company and also become shareholders of the post-takeover firm. Example 1: Consider two firms, X and Y, that compete in the same product market. Corporation X currently has one million shares outstanding, each with value $2. Firm Y has 500,000 shares on offer and share price $10. Firm Y is contemplating a takeover of corporation X, as it knows that corporation X is being run inefficiently. Firm Y estimates that, if it takes corporation X over, it could increase firm X’s net cash flow by $300,000 per year. Assume that these firms are infinitely lived. The relevant cost of capital for firm X is 10 per cent. Given the prior information, it is clear that, if firm Y does take over corporation X, the increase in X’s value would be the present value of a perpetuity paying $300,000 each year. This present value is $3m, which represents the gain from the merger.4 It is clear that, given that the merger creates value, it is socially desirable. However, the terms by which the merger actually occurs will dictate the net payoffs to the shareholders of X and Y. For the merger to occur, both net payoffs must be positive. 4 Make sure you can derive this PV for yourself. Assume, for example, that the merger is to occur by firm Y agreeing to purchase every share in firm X at a price of $3 per share. This implies that (as there are one million shares in firm X in issue) X’s shareholders get a total payout of $3m, which exceeds the value of their initial shareholding (i.e. $2m). Hence firm X’s shareholders are happy to participate in the merger, as their payoff is $1m. Firm Y’s shareholders are paying $3m for a firm which, under their management, will be worth $2m + $3m = $5m. Hence their gain is also positive at $2m, and they are happy to participate. Note that, quite obviously, the sum of the gains to X and Y shareholders is the total value creation of $3m. Another way in which this merger could have been financed is if firm Y offered to issue a certain amount of new shares and gave these to the shareholders of firm X instead of cash. Consider the following offer as an example. One new share in firm Y is exchanged for every four existing firm X shares. Note that this freshly issued equity will be a claim on the value of the merged enterprise and hence priced as such. The value of the merged firm will be the sum of the pre-merger values of X and Y plus the value created of $3m. The pre-merger value of X is $2m and that of Y is $5m. Hence the total value of the firm after the merger is $10m. After the merger there are 0.75m shares in issue. This comprises the original 0.5m shares in firm Y plus the 250,000 new shares issued.5 Hence the share price of the merged enterprise is: $ (8.2) The original shareholders of Y hold two-thirds of the equity of the merged enterprise, which has a value $6.67m. The value of their original position is $5m and hence they gain to the tune of $1.67m. The old X shareholders own one-third of the equity of the merged enterprise, which is worth $3.33m. Their gain is hence $1.33m, as the value of firm X pre-merger was $2m. Both sets of shareholders are winners therefore, and hence the 108 5 One new share was offered for every four old X shares. As there were originally one million X shares outstanding, this implies 250,000 new Y shares must be issued. Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers merger goes ahead. Again, note that the sum of the gains is $3m, the total value created. Example 2: Suppose you are the treasurer of Company A and you are investigating the possible acquisition of Company B. You have the following basic data: Company A B Next year’s expected earnings per share £5.00 £1.50 Next year’s expected dividends per share £3.00 £0.80 1,000,000 600,000 £90 £20 Number of shares Stock price You estimate that investors currently expect a steady growth of about 6 per cent in B’s earnings and dividends. Under new management this growth rate would be increased to 8 per cent per year, without any additional capital investment required. Let us first calculate the gain from the acquisition. To find the appropriate discount rate (r) for the common stock of Company B, we use the perpetual growth model of stock valuation: 0.80 = 20 ⇒ r = 0.10 r – 0.06 Under the new management, the value of the merged firm (call it AB) would be the value of Company A before the merger plus the value of B after the merger, or: ( 0.10$0.80 – 0.08 ( PVAB = (1,000,000 * $90) + 600,000 * = $114,000,000. The gain from the acquisition is then: Gain = PVAB – (PVA + PVB) = $114,000,000 – ($90,000,000 + $12,000,000) = $12,000,000. It is clear that, given that the merger creates value, it is again socially desirable. However, the costs of the merger for A will be typically different in a cash deal and in a stock deal. Let us calculate these costs under the two different payment methods. Let us start with the cost of acquisition in case of a cash deal. Suppose A pays $25 in cash for each share of B. Then: Cost = Cash Paid – PVB = ($25 * 600,000) – $12,000,000 = $3,000,000. Since the acquisition gain is larger than this cost, shareholders of both companies would be happy to make such a deal. Shareholders of B are paid $25 for their stock worth $20, and get in total the cost of the acquisition: ($25 – $20) * 600,000 = $3,000,000. The owners of A get the rest of the gain $12,000,000 – $3,000,000 = $9,000,000. Now let us see what happens in a stock deal. Suppose A offers one share of A for every three shares of B. Because this acquisition is financed with stock, we have to take into consideration the effect of the merger on the stock price of A. After the merger, there will be 1,200,000 shares outstanding (1,000,000 old shares plus 600,000/3 new shares given to the owners of B). Hence, the share price will be the value of AB after merger divided by the new total number of shares: $114,000,000/1,200,000 = $95.00. Therefore, the cost will be the number of shares sold to owners of B times the new price, minus PVB: Cost = ($95 * 200,000) – ($20 *600,000) = $7,000,000. This cost is more than twice the cost of the previous cash deal. However, the gain from the acquisition is still larger 109 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance and shareholders of both firms would be happy to perform it. Shareholders of B exchange three shares worth 3 * $20 = $60 for one share worth $95 and thus receive again the cost of the acquisition of $7,000,000. Shareholders of A get ($95 – $90) * 1,000,000 = $5,000,000 which is exactly the gain minus the cost of the stock deal. Finally, let us see how the costs of the cash offer and the share offer alter if expected growth rate of B is not changed by the merger. If the acquisition is for cash, the cost would not be changed since we still pay $25 per each share of B: Cost = $3,000,000. If the acquisition is for stock, the cost is different from the one calculated before. This is because the new growth rate affects the value of the merged company. This, in turn, affects the stock price of the merged company and, hence, the cost of the merger. It follows that the new value of the merged company is: PVAB = ($90 * 1,000,000) + ($20 * 600,000) = $102,000,000. The new share price will be: $102,000,000/1,200,000 = $85.00. Therefore: Cost = ($85 * 200,000) – ($20 * 600,000) = $5,000,000. Note that this is lower than the cost of $7,000,000 calculated before. The lower growth rate changes the post-valuation of the merged company and lowers the price of AB. Hence, the cost of a share deal goes down. The market for corporate control As a result of the separation of ownership and control, managers may not act in the firm owners’ best interest. Managers may: • exercise insufficient effort • make extravagant investments (Jensen (1986)) • use entrenchment strategies; that is, take actions that hurt shareholders in order to secure their position (Shleifer and Vishny (1989)) • increase their private benefits from running the firm by engaging in a variety of self-dealing behaviour (Jensen and Meckling (1976)). This moral hazard between firms’ managers and owners may be mitigated through corporate governance. A firm’s board of directors in principle monitors managers on behalf of owners. It is furthermore in charge of managers’ compensation, audits and oversight of risk management. Moral hazard between firms’ managers and owners may be mitigated through the market for corporate control. In the market for control, disciplinary takeovers, which are usually hostile, create value by substituting efficient teams for entrenched money-wasting managers. These disciplinary takeovers may be needed to keep managers on their toes if the board of directors is an ineffective monitor and, more generally, if corporate governance is failing. This is particularly important for firms with a disperse mass of small shareholders. However, as we will see in the following section, free-rider problems make hostile takeovers particularly difficult when ownership is disperse. The impossibility of efficient takeovers In the previous sections, we examined the types of merger activity commonly seen in reality and the motives for such activity generally given by managers. In this section, we will introduce you to a simple theoretical model of merger activity, which yields the result that any efficient takeover bid will fail.6 This extreme outcome comes from rational shareholders free-riding on the (effort and) firm value improvement delivered by a takeover raider. 110 The model developed in this section is based on Grossman and Hart (1980). Efficient takeover activity is defined as activity for which the increase in the market value of the acquired firm exceeds any associated costs. 6 Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers Assumptions Our assumptions here are as follows: • the firm is subject to a takeover bid from an external takeover raider • firm value will improve, if the bid succeeds: the value increase is common knowledge • the equity of the target firm is held by many, small shareholders • the raider incurs administrative takeover costs of c. Assume that the current firm value is y, and let the firm value if the takeover were to succeed be y + z. The takeover is efficient as the following condition holds: z > c. (8.3) The raider must gain at least 50 per cent of the shares to implement the takeover. Note, however, that as shareholders are assumed to be identical, if any one shareholder finds it profitable to tender their shares to the raider then all will. The raider offers a premium p over the current firm value to equity-holders for their shares. Hence, for the bid to be profitable for the raider we must have: z > p + c, (8.4) that is, the improvement in firm value must exceed the cost of takeover and the premium paid to original equity-holders. Consider the position of a single, small shareholder. As their shareholding is minor relative to the sum of all equity, they do not consider their decision to be pivotal. Assume that they believe that the bid will be successful. Then they will only sell their shares to the raider if: p > z, (8.5) that is, it is only in the shareholder’s interest to tender if the premium they get outweighs the money they would make by hanging on to their equity and profiting from the value improvement associated with the takeover. If the shareholder believes that the takeover bid will fail, then they will be indifferent between offering their shares to the raider and not offering them. Our key result can be derived from a comparison of equations 8.4 and 8.5. They are clearly contradictory, implying that the raider cannot simultaneously succeed with the bid and make a profit. Hence, profitable takeover activity cannot occur. A crucial assumption here is that all shareholders are small in size. This then implies that none of them perceive themselves to be pivotal to the success of the takeover bid. This results in all small shareholders attempting to free-ride on the value improvement offered by the raider and, ultimately, the bid then fails. Another way to see the result is as follows. A premium that allows the raider to make a profit must satisfy the following condition: p ∈ (0, z – c). (8.6) However, a premium in this region implies that shareholders are better off not selling to the raider and hanging on to their equity as: y + p < y + z – c < y + z. (8.7) 111 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance The first term in equation 8.7 is the money they get for selling to the raider, and the final term is the value of their shareholding if they do not sell (conditional on the bid being successful). Two ways to get efficient takeovers In light of casual and formal empirical evidence, the result of the previous section seems untenable. Most would argue that at least some of the takeovers that occur in reality lead to both the raider and the target shareholders making some money. This section provides two ways in which we can overturn the results from the previous section. Dilution Grossman and Hart (1980) first pointed out the free-riding problem we discussed in the preceding section. In the same paper they also indicated a solution to the free-riding problem. This solution was dilution. Dilution is the ability of a raider to extract value from the target, if they successfully complete the takeover. This might be done by placing themself in charge and paying themself an astronomical salary, selling the firm’s output to another corporation they own at a very low price, and other diverse means. Hence, if the takeover is successful and the raider dilutes the firm, the firm’s market value ends up being less than y + z (to use the notation of the previous section). To make the prior argument concrete, assume the raider can appropriate an amount φ of firm value if the takeover is successful. Hence, if shareholders believe the bid will be successful, they will be willing to tender their shares if offered a premium (over current value) that satisfies the following condition: p > z – φ. (8.8) The raider makes money if equation 8.4 holds, and this leads to the following condition for profitable takeover activity to occur: z – c > p > z – φ | φ > c. (8.9) The interpretation of equation 8.9 is simple – takeovers can be profitable if the amount the raider can grab through dilution exceeds the administrative cost of takeover. Note also that, once they gain control, the raider need not actually dilute the firm. Merely the threat of dilution allows the takeover to proceed. A final issue about dilution that should be addressed is the source of the raider’s ability to dilute. Grossman and Hart assume that the target firm is originally a private enterprise. The original owners of the firm then decide to take the firm public and write provisions that allow dilution into the corporate charter. These individuals do this in order to ensure that the firm is efficiently run in future years (i.e. they write in dilution provisions to allow efficient future takeover activity). Large shareholders (toehold) Another scenario in which efficient takeover activity might occur is when a single shareholder owns a large block of equity. In such a situation we can think of the large shareholder and the raider synonymously (i.e. it is the large shareholder who can possibly implement an efficient takeover). Sticking with the notation used in the Grossman and Hart (1980) analysis, assume that the large shareholder originally owns a proportion α of firm 112 Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers equity (toehold). Assuming no dilution, the condition for shareholders to tender if they believe the bid will succeed is again: p > z. (8.10) Hence, shareholders require a premium that exceeds the size of the value improvement. The condition that must hold for the large shareholder to profit is: z > (1 – α)p + c, (8.11) that is, the value improvement must exceed the cost of takeover, plus the premium the large shareholder must pay to buy the remaining (1 – α) of firm equity. Both equations 8.10 and 8.11 are satisfied when the following condition holds: αz > c. (8.12) Hence, large shareholders can implement efficient takeovers, when the proportion of the value improvement that accrues to their original holding exceeds the takeover cost. Thus our analysis tells us that large shareholders are important in that their existence allows the free-rider problem to be circumvented. This is exploited in Shleifer and Vishny (1986) who also relax the assumption of perfect information. In their analysis, the value improvement is only known by the large shareholder, and this provides another reason for the existence of takeover activity in the model. The role of the large shareholder is emphasised in some of the empirical predictions from their model. They show, for example, that firm values increase with the size of the large shareholding. The intuition for this is that a larger shareholding means more efficient takeover decisions and hence a firm with larger future values and hence greater current market value. Empirical evidence Are mergers and acquisitions value-enhancing? This section reviews empirical evidence from two types of studies: accounting and event studies. The first type, accounting studies, examine financial results (accounting data) to draw inferences about the underlying economic impact of mergers and acquisitions. These studies tend to investigate whether acquirers outperform their non-acquirer peers. Alternatively, these studies compare the performance of the combined firm following a merger or an acquisition with the performance obtaining prior to the transaction. Performance tends to be measured by net income, operating margin, or return on equity or assets. The second type, event studies, do not directly measure performance. Instead, these studies attempt to measure the value created by the merger or acquisition through abnormal stock returns around the announcement date of a tender offer. Hence, event studies rely on financial markets being efficient. Accounting studies The empirical evidence from accounting studies is mixed. Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987) investigate more than 5,000 mergers occurring between 1950 and 1975, calculate and compare the post-merger performance of acquiring firms with that of non-acquiring firms in the same industries, with performance being measured as return on assets, and report that performance is 1 to 2 per cent less for acquiring firms. 113 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance In contrast, Healy, Palepu and Ruback (1992) examine 50 large mergers between 1979 and 1983 and report improvement in performance of the combined firms following the mergers, where performance is measured by sales and profits. Asset productivity is furthermore shown to improve significantly following acquisitions. The difference in findings between both accounting studies may be due to differences in the motivation for mergers and acquisitions. The motivation for many of the mergers in the 1960s and 1970s (and much fewer in the 1980s) was diversification and there can be efficiency losses associated with diversification. Accounting studies are, however, vulnerable to discrepancies introduced by accounting for mergers and acquisitions. Event studies Empirical evidence from event studies suggests that shareholders from target firms gain from takeovers. This should not come as a surprise as target shareholders require a premium in order to induce them to sell their shares to the acquiring firm. Jensen and Ruback (1983) report that target share prices increase, on average, by about 16 to 30 per cent around the date of the announcement of a tender offer. Empirical evidence reported by Jarrell, Brickley and Netter (1988) suggests that these returns increased substantially during the 1980s to an average of about 53 per cent. Jensen and Ruback (1983) furthermore report that the average return to shareholders from target firms in negotiated mergers is, however, only about 10 per cent. The empirical evidence from event studies on returns to shareholders of bidding firms tends to be quite mixed: returns to bidders are, on average, small, time-varying, but may be positive or negative. For instance, Jarrell and Poulsen (1989) show that the announcement return to bidder in tender offers dropped from a statistically significant 5 per cent gain in the 1960s to an insignificant 1 per cent loss in the 1980s. The means of payment used for the transaction is furthermore shown to have a major effect on returns to bidders. For instance, Travlos (1987) finds that the average return on the two days around the announcement of a cash offer is only marginally different from zero (+0.24 per cent). In contrast, in acquisitions financed by an exchange of equity, stock prices of bidding firms fall, on average, by about 1.5 per cent. The means of payment may hence act as a signal for the quality of the bidder. Consistent with the pecking order theory reviewed in Chapter 6 (Myers and Majluf (1984)), bidders offer stock when they believe that their stock is overvalued. A stock offer may furthermore indicate that the bidder was unable to get any financial backing from a bank or another financial institution. Adding the bidder and target returns generates positive returns, implying that, on average, there is a net gain to shareholders around the time of the merger or acquisition. For instance, Bradley, Desai and Kim (1988) provide evidence suggesting that successful tender offers increase the combined value of the merging firms by an average of 7.4 per cent or $117m (stated in 1984 dollars). The empirical evidence from event studies hence suggests that mergers and acquisitions are, on average, value enhancing. Summary In this chapter we have given you an overview of the facts involved in, and theory surrounding, mergers and takeovers. The main lesson of this chapter is that mergers that should go ahead (i.e. efficient merger activity) are those that are positive NPV transactions. See equation 8.1. 114 Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers Such positive NPV can come from exploitation of economies of scale in production or sales (strategic mergers), removal of bad management and elimination of inefficiencies (financial mergers) or possibly through the purchase of firms in an unrelated industry but with a strong portfolio of possible investment projects (conglomerate mergers). We discussed theoretical models indicating that such efficient merger activity may be blocked in economies without frictions or information asymmetries. The source of problems here is shareholder free riding. The prevention of profitable takeovers by free riding is shown to disappear when allowances are made for dilution, large shareholders and asymmetric information. Towards the end of the chapter, we investigate whether mergers and acquisitions are value-enhancing. Empirical evidence from event studies suggests that mergers and acquisitions create, on average, joint value. Most of the value created is, however, appropriated by the shareholders of target firms. A reminder of your learning outcomes Having completed this chapter, and the Essential reading, you should be able to: • discuss motivations for merger activity • analyse simple numerical examples of efficient takeover activity • detail the argument of Grossman­–Hart (1980) regarding the impossibility of efficient takeovers • present ways in which this analysis can be modefied to permit takeovers to occur. Key terms asymmetric information bidders capital structure clientele model conglomerate mergers corporate governance dilution disciplinary takeover efficient takeovers event studies financial mergers free-riding frictionless markets Grossman–Hart model large shareholders mergers and acquisitions strategic mergers targets takeover premium toehold 115 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Sample examination questions 1. Present the assumptions behind, and give a derivation of, the Grossman–Hart analysis, which implies that efficient takeover activity is impossible. 2. Describe the dilution solution to the preceding solution as suggested by Grossman and Hart. 3. How does the existence of a large shareholder affect the Grossman– Hart result? 4. Exporting firm Euro Importing has a market value of €100 million. There are one million shares outstanding, 20 per cent of them are controlled by the CEO who is the original founder. The present value of the firm’s profits is €130 million, however the CEO uses up €30 million of firm value for pet projects that do not add value to the firm. All other shares are controlled by dispersed shareholders. An asset management firm worth €500 million, and which has five million shares outstanding, is considering acquiring Euro Importing. a. What is the current price per share of Euro Importing? b. If the acquirer buys 51 per cent of the shares, it would control the firm and cancel wasteful perk spending. What is the maximum the acquirer would be willing to pay for 51 per cent? What if purchasing 51 per cent also involved €1 million in additional fees? c. The acquirer announces that it will attempt a takeover of Euro Importing by purchasing shares at the price in (b). Assume €1 million fees as in (b). What happens to the price per share if (i) the market believes the raid will succeed; (ii) the market believes the raid will fail. What does a rational investor do if the rest of the market believes (i)? If the rest of the market believes (ii)? Is there an inconsistency? What happens to the price per share of the asset management firm if (i)? If (ii)? d. Suppose half of the dispersed shareholders believe the acquirer succeeds and half believe that he will fail. Does the raid succeed? e. How many shareholders are willing to sell if the offer price is €130? How many are willing to sell if the offer price is €100? Assume you can linearly interpolate the probability that a shareholder succeeds between these two extreme values. What price must be paid for the raid to succeed? Is it worth it to the acquirer? What if the fees were €6 million? f. Suppose that after buying the firm, the acquirer can also use up €30 million on private benefits. At what price would the shareholders now be willing to sell? Relate this to Grossman and Hart’s solution to the free rider problem. g. Explain why current ownership would be willing to outbid the acquirer. 116 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging Aim of the chapter The aim of this chapter is to understand why and how companies manage risks in their course of operation. With this aim in mind, we will discuss the reasons, typical financial instruments and the associated costs of risk management. Learning objectives At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain why and how companies manage risk • explain and evaluate the cost of hedging • explain covered and uncovered interest rate parity, and analyse the associated arbitrage possibilities. Essential reading Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 26 (Managing Risk). Further reading Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston, MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 21 (Risk Management and Corporate Strategy), 22 (The Practice of Hedging), and 23 (Interest Rate Risk Management) Introduction In the previous chapters, we have analysed: • valuation and investment decisions • dividend decisions • financing decisions. One of the most important roles of a CFO in running a business is to manage the potential risks associated with the operations. In this chapter, we study risk management and hedging. In particular, we would like to understand which risks should be hedged, and how to find the appropriate instruments to hedge these risks. We are going to talk about why and how firms manage risks. We will consider three main reasons why firms hedge their risks: • bankruptcy costs • cost of financial distress • risk averse managers. Then we will analyse several possible instruments to reduce risks: • insurance • future contracts 117 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance • forward contracts • swaps. We will elaborate on each of those and see how they can be beneficial to reduce future uncertainty. However, managing risks via hedging is typically not for free. We will talk about the two main costs of hedging: • transaction costs • risk premium. Finally, we will briefly talk about one application of futures for hedging in the foreign exchange market – the carry trade, and the resulting covered and uncovered interest rate parity. Why do firms hedge? Let us first understand the definition of hedging: hedging is a set of financial transactions which offset the risk of a real asset. When the real asset rises in value, the hedge loses money. On the other hand, when the real asset falls in value, the hedge makes money. For example, suppose you have one share of Facebook, but are afraid that the share price might drop. You can hedge this risk by buying a put option on the stock: when the stock price rises, the put option loses money (all else equal); however, when the price drops, the put is increasing in value, thereby offsetting part of the losses on the stock. Essentially, the hedge should be negatively correlated to the real asset as we will see later on. If the hedge is perfect, the gains from the hedge and the losses from the real asset are perfectly correlated. This means that the total return of the portfolio consisting of the real asset and the hedge should be a constant. Imperfect hedge is when the portfolio return still fluctuates so there are still some residual risks. An example of a simple perfect hedge in the previous situation would be a short sell of one Facebook share – the total return of the portfolio will then be 0 (assuming no transaction costs). What are the consequences of hedging? The most important one is that risks are transferred, not eliminated. For example, suppose you are worried about getting laid off from your job and want to hedge this risk by buying unemployment insurance. The risk of getting laid off is still present though: the fact that you own insurance does not eliminate the possibility of getting unemployed. What changes is that now someone else is bearing the risk – the government in this case. Another consequence of hedging is that if the insurer cannot diversify the risk (the risk is systematic), then the hedger has to compensate by paying a premium. Thus, even a perfect hedge of a systematic risk loses money on average. Unemployment insurance is one of the many hedging activities we are involved in our everyday life (although we might not use the word hedging to describe them). Individuals hedge personal risks all the time: they buy health, home owner or auto insurance to reduce the risks of losses. How does insurance work in practice? Quite simple: the individual pays a fixed amount called the insurance premium, to the insurance company. In exchange, the insurance company pays the variable cash flow (the loss) in case of hazards: sickness, the home burns down or there is a car accident. If there is no insurance event during the contract, the individual just pays the insurance premium but gets nothing in return. However, if there is an accident during the insurance contract, the insurance company steps in and covers part or all of the losses. Hence, by buying insurance, we perform a financial transaction that offsets the risk of a real asset – we hedge. Insurance, as well as hedging in general, 118 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging is not a zero-NPV transaction. As we briefly mentioned earlier, the hedger pays a premium to the insurer. On top of that, insurance companies have advantages and disadvantages in bearing risk. Let us talk about advantages first. One of the key advantages is that insurers have better skills in estimating probabilities – they have more data and can evaluate more precisely the likelihood of an insurance event. For example, they can estimate the probability of your house burning down based on the location of the house, the number of rooms, the number of houses burned down in the area for the past years, etc. Insurance companies have also more skills in identifying risk-reduction techniques. For example, in the USA, insurance companies use software to evaluate the driving skills of the individuals they insure; based on the evaluations, the insurance premium can be higher or lower. In response, individuals driving the cars might reduce their driving risk in order to get higher scores. Another key advantage of insurance companies is that, by pooling many individual risks, they can diversify the risks (recall the benefits of diversification and the law of large numbers). However, there are some disadvantages in bearing risk. First, just like usual companies, insurers have to pay wages to their employees, and bear other administrative costs. Second, and more important, insurance creates a bulk of potential adverse selection and moral hazard problems. Let us take house insurance as an example. Suppose there is a home owner (Home Owner A) who knows better than the insurance company about potential issues with their house that can cause an insurance event. For example, they know that there are some electricity issues that can cause a fire in the house but the insurance company is unaware of those. If there are many home owners like Home Owner A in the market, the insurance company will be unable to distinguish between them and honest owners. As a result, it will be charging too high insurance premium assuming every customer is like Home Owner A. This could lead to the entire insurance market breaking down as nobody would find it optimal to buy insurance at the high premium. This is the adverse selection problem. To illustrate the moral hazard problem, let us take car insurance as an example. Suppose there is a risky driver with a luxurious car who would like to insure against a car crash. However, once fully insured, they no longer find it rational to drive responsibly. Even if they crash their expensive car, the insurance company will compensate them with money to buy a new one, so why should they care about the damages? This is the moral hazard problem – one does not fully bear the consequences of one’s own actions. The last disadvantage of bearing risk by insurance companies is that the risk pool may have correlated risks. Remember, the crucial assumption of the law of large numbers is that the random draws are uncorrelated. Once this assumption is violated, we cannot use the law to estimate probabilities correctly. Assuming no correlation was one of the most serious mistakes in finance. In the financial crisis of 2008, one of the largest insurance companies, AIG offered credit risk insurance to a pool of mortgages, which was assumed to have uncorrelated defaults. However, many of these mortgages were correlated which caused huge losses to AIG. For example, the mortgage payers could default simultaneously if they lost their job at the same time, or if the economy-wide house price went down. Some of these mortgage payers worked for the same factory so when the factory was closed down and workers laid off, their defaults suddenly became highly correlated. 119 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Up to now, we looked at insurance from the insurance companies’ perspective. Let us now turn to the insuring side. Since hedging transactions are not free (not zero-NPV transactions), do firms need to hedge? In a Modigliani–Miller world, the answer is no. Why? First, there should be no consequence of firm failure as all the failure risks should be fairly priced. Thus, there should be no room for lowering bankruptcy costs by hedging. Second, under the MM assumptions, investors can undertake the same transactions as firms and hence, can hedge on their own. Therefore, there should be no scope for separate insurance companies that perform the hedging on behalf of investors. In practice, however, hedging is an important aspect of firms’ operations. So why do firms hedge? Some of the MM assumptions must be violated. In the remainder of this section, we provide three reasons for that: • bankruptcy costs • cost of financial distress • risk averse manager. Let us elaborate on each. Bankruptcy costs How do we reduce bankruptcy costs? One way to achieve this target is by reducing the probability of default. Sometimes, however, the financial market for the risk may not exist. For example, suppose you are a UK company, and you want to hedge against unfavourable outcomes for your activities in case London becomes a less important financial centre. However, a contract that pays off in this case might simply not exist. A possible way to hedge is then for the company to establish a subsidiary outside the UK, thereby diversifying its activities. Another obvious non-hedging approach to reduce the default probability is to avoid any kind of leverage altogether. In the extreme case, when the firm has no debt, there is zero probability of default. Would this be optimal for the company? Not necessarily. Recall companies can increase their value by taking debt because of the interest tax shield. Hence, they can find it optimal to take on leverage to improve valuation indicators even though this increases default risk. There are two main types of leverage debts that companies manage: financial leverage assets , and operating fixed costs leverage total costs . ( ( ( ( Alternatively, firms use financial contracts to lower the default probability and thus, bankruptcy costs. By using financial arrangements with other entities, a company can shift resources from good outcomes to bad outcomes, thereby reducing the cash flow risk. The firm’s aggregate performance (including the payment associated with the financial arrangements) in the good state would be lower, but the firm’s performance in the bad state would be less devastating. Hence, these financial arrangements reduce the probability of bankruptcy in the bad state. Let us illustrate the last point with a simple example which shows how hedging activities can decrease the default probability. Example. Hedging with financial contracts Suppose two firms: A and B, have the following cash flows shown in Table 9.1. Both states are equally likely. Whenever the cash flow is less than 60, the firm fails. Bankruptcy costs are 20 per cent of firm value, so if the cash flow is 50, the firm fails and its value will be 40 due to bankruptcy. 120 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging State 1 State 2 Firm A 50 100 Firm B 100 50 Table 9.1: Cash flows in the different states. The firm value (for both A and B) without hedging (since the probability of each state is 50 per cent) is 0.5*100 + 0.5*50*(1 – 20%) = 70 But can the firms do better than that? Can they write a contract that allows them both to avoid bankruptcy and the loss of 20 per cent in the bad state? Yes. Suppose the two firms can sign the following contract: in state 1, firm B gives firm A 25; in state 2, firm A gives firm B 25. The new cash flows are shown in Table 9.2. State 1 State 2 Firm A 75 75 Firm B 75 75 Table 9.2: New cash flows in the different states. In this case, there is no bankruptcy. The firm value is 0.5*75+0.5*75=75. This is larger than the firm value without hedging (70). The value of hedging is 75 – 70 = 5 for each firm, which are exactly the savings from avoiding the bankruptcy loss of 20%*50 = 10 in the bad state. Since the probability of each state is 50%, the expected savings are 50%*10 = 5. Cost of financial distress This type of cost arises if the company has investment opportunities at a time when the company’s cash flow is low. The firm can have many positive NPV projects but if there is not enough money to invest in them, the company might be forced to sell securities at lower prices in order to attract funding for the projects. This is costly and can also lead to higher perceived risk. In some cases, firms might be even forced to forego the positive NPV projects because of a lack of capital to invest. Firms would like to hedge against such unfavourable outcomes. A crucial point to consider is the correlation between investment opportunities and cash flows. If investment opportunities and cash flows are not constant then hedging can be value enhancing or value destroying. Let us elaborate on this. In case cash flows and positive NPV opportunities are positively correlated, hedging is not beneficial. If there are no positive NPV projects when a firm’s cash flow is low, and, to the contrary, if there are many positive NPV projects when a firm’s cash flow is high, the firm does not need to hedge. It has enough money to invest in the good state but does not need money in the bad state as there are no projects then either. Hence, in this case, hedging does not create value. On the other hand, if cash flows and positive NPV opportunities are negatively correlated, hedging is beneficial. If the firm has many positive NPV projects at a time when cash flows are low, and, to the contrary, has few positive NPV projects at a time when cash flows are high, hedging can be profitable because it pays off exactly when the firm needs cash the most. Let us illustrate these crucial points with two simple examples which show the importance of correlation for hedging activities. In the first one, hedging creates no value, whereas in the second, it creates benefits for the company. 121 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Example. Positive correlation and hedging Suppose cash flows and investment opportunities are positively correlated. The cash flow is either 60 or 100 with equal probability. A firm has an investment project that costs 75 and returns NPV of 20 in the good state (when cash flow is 100) only. If the firm hedges, it has cash flow of 0.5*60 + 0.5*100 = 80 in both states. In the good state, it has also the positive NPV project that gives additional 20 (see Table 9.3). State 1 State 2 Unhedged Asset Cash flow 60 100 + 20 Hedged Asset Cash flow 80 80 + 20 Table 9.3: Cash flows with positive correlation. If the firm hedges it has an expected cash flow of 0.5*80 + 0.5*(80 + 20) = 90. If it does not hedge, the expected cash flow is still 90: 0.5*60 + 0.5*120 = 90. Hence, there are no gains from hedging as the expected cash flow from hedging equals that from not hedging. Let us now consider the opposite case when hedging does create benefits. Example. Negative correlation and hedging Suppose now that cash flows and investment opportunities are negatively correlated. The cash flow is again either 60 or 100 with equal probability. However, the firm has an investment project that costs 75 and returns NPV of 20 in the bad state (when cash flow is 60) only. If the firm hedges, it has again a cash flow of 80 in both states. However, now in the bad state, it also has the positive NPV project that gives additional 20 (see Table 9.4). State 1 State 2 Unhedged Asset Cash flow 60 100 Hedged Asset Cash flow 80+20 80 Table 9.4: Cash flows with negative correlation. Thus, if the firm hedges, it has an expected cash flow of 0.5*(80 + 20) + 0.5*80 = 90. If it does not hedge, the expected cash flow is only 80: 0.5*60 + 0.5*100 = 80. Hence, there are gains from hedging as the expected cash flow from hedging is larger than that from not hedging. Where does the benefit come from? It is due to the fact that with hedging, the company does not forego the positive NPV project and gets the full NPV of 20 with a probability of 50%: 0.5*20 = 10 = 90 – 80. Risk averse manager Another reason for hedging is that firms’ managers are risk averse. As such, they would be willing to diversify the risk of being dependent on the success of their own company. However, it is not easy for them to do so. Compared to outside investors who can easily buy a share of a similar company, or buy downside protection with options, managers cannot undertake such transactions. Why? Let us think. Suppose you are an outside investor who holds shares in Google. You are worried that the share price might drop so you decide to hedge your position by buying put options (remember, these appreciate in value if the price drops). This is a reasonable hedge that minimises the risk of Google doing badly. Now suppose that you are one of Google’s managers and you decide to perform the same transaction. Should the company allow you to do so? If they do, then you might be incentivised to bring down the company and profit on your put position. This simple example illustrates that it is 122 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging optimal to expose managers to risks in order to maintain their incentives. If managers’ compensation is tied to the firm’s success, this creates no conflict of interest and forces managers to work hard to increase the firm’s value. Hedging via bearish positions such as the put described above, might create conflicts of interests and destroy managers’ incentives. At the end of this section, let us discuss the potential danger of ‘overhedging’, that is speculation. Speculation is one of the bad reasons for hedging. However, in practice, it is difficult to differentiate hedging from speculation. Hedging risk requires sophistication but the treasury departments of many firms do not have the knowledge and/or guidance on how to reduce risk, especially at the highest level. In fact, firms may be tempted to gamble as in many cases those hedging get more credit if they make money rather than avoid losing money. This can be dangerous and, as we are going to see in the example below, even detrimental in some cases. Example. China Eastern Airlines The largest costs for a typical airline company are fuel costs, which directly depend on the oil price. Higher oil prices mean higher costs and lower profits. To hedge the risk of high oil prices, airline companies bet on the increase of oil prices. If the price increases, they make money on the bet but lose money from their main business. To the contrary, if the oil price tanks, they lose money on the hedge but get more profits from their airline business. China Eastern Airlines decided to perform the hedge outlined above. Prior to 2008, the oil price was rising and this hedge delivered money to the company at the time when it was losing profits from the airline business. Based on the good results, the company’s management turned the usual hedge into speculation on oil prices. They over-hedged in 2008, betting on oil price increase much more than what was necessary for their normal demand of aviation oil. The oil price dropped and in usual circumstances this would have been good news for the company as it had to pay lower fuel costs. However, due to its speculation activities, the company accumulated staggering loss of approximately 6 billion RMB on top of an operating loss of 14 billion. This drove the firm’s leverage ratio to 115 per cent. Ultimately, the firm went bankrupt. The example of China Eastern Airlines illustrates the potential disastrous consequence of turning hedging into speculation. Activity Which of the following firms may be more likely to hedge risks? Give a brief explanation: a. Private firms where investors are not diversified. b. Opaque firms with significant asymmetric information problems. c. Intangible firms that are more exposed to costs of financial distress. d. All of the above described firms. Typical financial instruments for hedging After we established several reasons for firms to manage risks via hedging, the next question is: how to perform the hedge? In this section, we will introduce four types of financial contracts that are commonly used for hedging purposes: • insurance • future contracts (aka futures) 123 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance • forward contracts • swaps. Futures, forward contracts and swaps belong to the asset class of derivatives. Derivatives are financial agreements/instruments/contracts whose returns are linked to, or derived from, the performance of underlying assets such as equity, bonds, currencies or commodities. We are already familiar with some basic derivatives: call and put options. Remember, the call option gives you the right, but not the obligation to buy the underlying asset in the future for a price fixed today; the put option gives you a similar right but to sell the asset. The value of both these simple derivatives is derived from the price of the underlying asset. For the remainder of this section we are going to discuss each type of financial contract used for hedging in more detail. Let us start with insurance. We already briefly talked about the main features of this type of hedging, so let us summarise the key points. In an insurance contract, the firm pays a fixed amount (the insurance premium) in exchange for the insurance company paying the variable cash flow (the loss) instead of the firm. This exchanges a variable cash flow for a fixed one. Insurance is against (mostly idiosyncratic) risk. By selling many policies, the insurance company diversifies much of the risk internally as it pools many idiosyncratic risks that cancel each other out. Moreover, because of the law of large numbers, the insurance company is able to predict the fraction of insurance events for the pool. Essentially, the probability is no longer uncertain but deterministic. The only risk which is left in the insurance company is the systematic risk, which is passed to shareholders through the securities market, where the security holders diversify the risk. Forwards and futures are another way of hedging the future uncertainty. They are agreements to sell an asset at a future date at a fixed price set today. The transaction price set today is called the forward/future price. For example, an airline company might be worried that in a year’s time the price of oil might be too high, hence increasing costs. To hedge this risk, the firm can buy a one-year futures contract, fixing the oil price today. This allows the company to get rid of the uncertainty related to future prices. Many assets have future markets including agricultural commodities (e.g. corn and soybeans), non-agricultural commodities (e.g. gold or fuel oil) and financial assets (e.g. 30-year government bonds or Swiss Francs). In practice, most contracts are not physically settled, i.e. the actual commodity is not usually delivered (sometimes delivery is not allowed for commodities like wind, for example). Traders usually reverse their position before the contract expires to have a net exposure of 0. For example, if you enter in a long oil futures contract maturing in one year, you can enter into a short futures contract with the same notional any time before the maturity, which would cancel your long position. Although quite similar, futures and forward contracts have some differences. Most importantly, futures contracts are standardised and are traded on exchanges. This means that the counterparty of your futures contract is the exchange. This decreases the counterparty risk. To the contrary, forward contracts are not standardised and are traded overthe-counter. This means that there is no intermediary between the long and the short side of the contract and that the risk of the counterparty defaulting is much higher. 124 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging Futures prices are closely related to spot prices observed in the future. In particular, future prices are one possible predictor of expected spot prices in the future. Is this predictor good enough? Not always. Why? Because of the risk premium. We will elaborate more on this in the next section. Lastly, let us discuss swaps as a way to hedge risks. A swap is an exchange of one set of cash flows (e.g. cash flows on a floating rate loan) for another of equivalent market value (e.g. cash flows on a fixed rate loan). Essentially, they are a sequence of futures contracts. Let us illustrate the mechanics of swaps with a simple example that shows how swaps can be beneficial in hedging mismatch between assets and liabilities. Example. Swap There are two firms: CRST and Hanson. CRST receives LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate), which is floating, but CRST a fixed liability. Thus, it is exposed to the risk that the floating rate might decrease and hence the company will have insufficient assets to cover its fixed-rate liability. Hanson, on the other hand, receives fixed rate but is liable for LIBOR. Thus, it is exposed to the risk that the floating rate might increase and hence Hansen will have insufficient assets to cover its floating-rate liability. Can the two firms sign a contract that allows both of them to hedge the floating versus fixed risk mismatch? Yes! CRST and Hanson can enter into an interest rate swap: CRST agrees to pay a floating rate to Hanson and Hanson agrees to pay a fixed interest rate (called the swap rate) to CRST. This way, both of them get rid of the uncertainty associated with the future LIBOR. The swap rate is always set such that the transaction has zero NPV. Suppose, in our example, the swap rate is 8 per cent. Figure 9.1 illustrates the mechanics of the contract. CRST receives LIBOR and pays it immediately to Hansen as a part of the swap contract. In return, CRST gets the fixed 8 per cent swap rate which allows CRST to pay the fixed 8 per cent liability to the lender. Analogously, Hansen receives the fixed rate of 8 per cent and pays it as a part of the swap contract. In return, it receives LIBOR from CRST which allows Hansen to cover the LIBOR liability: LIBOR Hanson PLC CRST Swap rate = 8% 8% Lender LIBOR Lender Figure 9.1: The swap contract between CRST and Hansen. A final remark on swap contracts is that there is a significant counterparty risk – that is, the risk that the hedge evaporates. In the example above, either CRST or Hansen might run away from the swap contract. 125 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Cost of risk management As mentioned earlier, risk management is not free. Usually, we have to pay some costs to transfer our risks to someone else. In this section, we will talk about two main costs of hedging: transaction costs and risk premium. Let us start with transaction costs. Typically, to complete a hedge, the firm will have to pay transaction costs: e.g. brokerage commissions and losses to more informed traders. Consider a simple example: you decide to buy an asset as a hedge, but a second later want to reverse the hedge by selling the same asset. Even assuming the price did not move in that one second, you will not be able to sell the asset for the price you bought it. Why? Because of the bid–ask spread. You buy at the ask price, but you sell at the bid price. Typically, the ask is larger than the bid so you lose money if you reverse the trade immediately. This loss is the profit of the market maker. In the early 1980s, the bid–ask spread for swaps exceeded 100 basis points at times, which is a significant number for firms that hedge frequently. A one per cent bid– ask spread means that they would lose the entire capital in 100 roundtrip transactions. By 1995, the bid–ask spread was significantly lower at 2 basis points. Now, let us talk about the risk premium. Let us take futures as an example. The future price is set today but will be paid next year. The spot price is the price at which you can buy the commodity today. Is the future price an unbiased estimate of the future spot price? No. If there is a positive risk premium, then the two will differ. Let us think why. Intuitively, when you buy a futures contract, you eliminate the uncertainty about future spot prices. No matter what the spot price is at the maturity of the contract, you can buy at the futures price. However, your counterparty does have to worry about the uncertainty. She has promised to sell the asset at the futures price, but, assuming she does not have the asset, she has to buy it at the spot price observed in the future. Hence, she bears the risk that the spot price will increase a lot, thereby causing her to suffer losses. To compensate her for this risk, we usually have to pay a premium, i.e. to agree on a futures price that is different than the expected spot price. Now, let us see the source of the premium (or the bias) mathematically. A futures contract is a zero-sum game: the losses of the one party are equal to the gains of the other party. In other words, the NPV of a futures contract is always 0. Hence, E (spot price) Future price 0 =0 − NPV(Future contract for seller) = 1+ r 1 + r commodity value future Assume no default, so rfuture = rrisk-free Rearranging, we get: Future price = E0 (Spot price) * (1 + rF) / (1 + rC), where rF is the risk free rate, rC is the commodity return. According to the CAPM, rC = rF + β * Market Risk Premium. β = 0 implies rC = rF and hence, Future price = E0 (spot price) β > 0 implies rC> rF and hence, Future price < E0 (spot price) β < 0 implies rC< rF and hence, Future price > E0 (spot price) The intuition is that the seller contracts away a systematic risk, so he offers a discount in future price as a compensation for risk to the buyer. The discount may be positive (Future price < E0 (spot price)) or negative (Future price > E0 (spot price)). The sign depends on whether the asset is a pro-cyclical (tanks in bad times, positive) or counter-cyclical (increases in 126 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging value in bad times, negative b). Consider, for example, an owner selling gold through a futures contract. Gold is a good hedge against bad times, so has a negative b. Hence, rC< rF and (1 + rF) / (1 + rC) > 1 which means (Future price > E0 (spot price). The seller of a gold futures contract loses the benefit of gold to appreciate in value in bad times by fixing the futures price today. He requires compensation for this; hence, the future price is above the expected spot price. To conclude, the risk premium is an important cost of hedging. Depending on the b of the asset, this premium may be positive or negative, causing the future price to be different than the expected spot price. Interest rate parity and carry trade Finally, after talking about derivatives as a way of hedging, let us briefly discuss some basics of the financial derivatives pricing. In this section, we will focus on the foreign exchange market. The foreign exchange market is the market where one currency is traded against another one. It is, arguably, the biggest market on the planet and is populated by very large institutional investors. There are also future contracts in this market – investors can take long or short positions on the future exchange rate between two currencies. What is the fair future price in the exchange market? Let us think. Suppose you are a US investor who wants to borrow for one year. You can directly borrow at the US interest rate. Alternatively, you can borrow in any other country, say, the UK, for the same period of time: you convert the pounds to dollars today, simultaneously fix the future exchange rate by entering into a futures contract, and then convert dollars to pounds in one year, to repay the UK loan. If there is no arbitrage, these two ways of borrowing should cost you the same. Hence, the future price should depend on the interest rates observed in the USA and UK. Let us illustrate this arbitrage pricing argument with an explicit example. Example. Interest rate parity Company ABC has decided to borrow $10M for one year. It is currently all equity financed, so we treat the debt as having zero default risk. If it borrows in the US market, it will have to pay 6 per cent interest. If it borrows in the UK market, however, it will have to pay only 2 per cent. The current exchange rate is £1=$1.25. Should the company borrow at the lower UK interest rate instead of at the higher US rate? Let us first calculate ABC’s obligation if it borrows in pounds. It needs to borrow $10M, which is equivalent to 10M 1 .25 = £8M. The principal and interest payments due next year will be the amount borrowed times the rate: 8*(1 + 0.02) = £8.16M. What is ABC’s obligation if it borrows in US dollars? It is simply the principal and interest payments in dollars: 10M*1.06 = $10.6M. It appears that borrowing pounds is much cheaper, 2 per cent interest versus 6 per cent interest. But is it? Not necessarily. It depends on the exchange rate tomorrow. If the pound appreciates against the dollar and ABC borrows pounds, then ABC may end up paying back a lot more in terms of dollars. For example, suppose a year later, 1£ = $2. Then the total liability in pounds is £8.16M * 2 = $16.32M. This is much higher than if borrowed in dollars ($10.6M). By borrowing in another currency, ABC is exposed to the exchange rate risk which might be substantial. Suppose now that ABC wants to borrow in pounds (for example because of better tax deals). Is it possible to hedge the exchange rate risk? Yes! 127 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance The company can use a currency forward contract to lock down the FX tomorrow. Suppose ABC can sign a currency forward contract on the £/$ exchange rate. How many contracts (face value) does the company need? What is the forward price? If ABC borrows in pounds, it needs to buy back £8.16M. The forward price must make sure that the company is indifferent between borrowing in pounds and in dollars, i.e. that £8.16M = $10.6M in a year’s time. Namely, the forward price must be £1=$1.3. As today £1=$1.25<$1.3, the forward price implies the pound will appreciate, making borrowing in pounds less attractive. What if the forward price is larger than $1.3, say, £1=$1.4? That is an arbitrage. Take the following strategy: today, borrow $1.25, convert into £1 and invest at the UK risk-free rate of 2%. Simultaneously, sign a forward contract for £1.02 at the observed forward price of £1=$1.4. In a year’s time, the investment returns £1.02, we use the forward contract to convert it into dollars: 1.02*1.4 = $1.428. We use part of this money to repay the dollar debt with 6 per cent interest: $1.25*1.06 = $1.325. The rest is the arbitrage profit: $1.428-$1.325 = 0.103. This example shows that the forward price should be uniquely linked to the spot exchange rate and to the interest rates in the two countries. Whenever this relationship is violated, we can construct an arbitrage. Let us generalise this relationship, based on the logic in the ABC example. Consider two ways to borrow $1 today: 1. Directly borrow $1 today and repay $(1+r$) in a year. 2. Borrow £fx£/$ today which is equivalent to $1 at today’s FX (foreign exchange) rate. Need to repay £fx£/$ * (1+r£) in a year. You can lock down the liability in dollars by entering a one-year forward contract today. The dollar liability in a year will be £ By the no-arbitrage argument we saw before, it must be that the two ways of borrowing are equivalent, i.e. (1+r$)=£fx£/$ * (1+r£)/F£/$. This is the ‘covered interest rate parity’. In the ABC example, 1.06 = 1.25 −1 1.02 1.3 . If covered interest rate parity fails, then there is an arbitrage opportunity. In reality it holds very well. Finally, what if we do not lock down the exchange rates in the future through future contracts? If we believe the forward rate F should equal the expected FX rate in a year, then the formula is called ‘uncovered interest rate parity’: (1 + r$) = fx£/$ * (1 + r£) / E[fx£/$]. Note the use of the uncertain instead of the deterministic E[fx£/$] in the formula F£/$. If we hold the positions in foreign currency and close them using random future spot exchange rate, then typically there is a non-zero return. In other words, the uncovered interest rate parity fails in reality: currency with higher interest rate tends to appreciate. Based on this, traders have developed a strategy called the carry trade: borrow low interest currency, buy government bond in high interest rate currency; then exchange it back to low interest currency and pay back the debt. There are two sources of profit in the strategy: from the interest rate spread and from the currency appreciation. For instance, in 2016–2017, the exchange rate increased, i.e. the pound depreciated against the dollar, although the pound interest rate was lower than the dollars. Hence, if you borrowed in pounds and invested in dollars over that period, you would not only gain because of the interest rate difference, but also because the dollar would be worth more in terms of pounds It is important to note, however, 128 Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging that the non-zero return is stochastic, hence the carry trade is not an arbitrage opportunity – there is some risk. Historically, the carry trade has experienced occasional very large losses when the exchange rates moved dramatically over short periods of time. Activities 1. Which of the following statements about futures contracts is false? Select only one: a. Futures contracts are generally more illiquid than forward contracts and are traded anonymously on an exchange at a publicly observed market price. b. Traders are required to post collateral, called margin, when selling or buying commodities through futures contracts. c. Both the seller and the buyer can get out of the contract at any time by selling it to a third party at the current market price. d. Futures prices are not prices that are paid today. They are prices agreed today, but to be paid in the future. 2. In September 2004, the spot exchange rate for the Euro against the US Dollar was $1.7188/€. At the same time the one-year interest rate in the USA was 4.85 per cent and the one-year interest rate in Europe was 3.15 per cent. Based on these rates, what is the one-year forward exchange rate that is consistent with no arbitrage? Choose the closest answer. Select one: a. $1.6/€. b. $1.9/€. c. $1.7/€. d. $1.5/€. A reminder of your learning outcomes At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and activities, you should be able to: • explain why and how companies manage risk • explain and evaluate the cost of hedging • explain covered and uncovered interest rate parity, and analyse the associated arbitrage possibilities. Key terms Carry trade Covered interest rate parity Forward contracts Future contracts Hedging Insurance Swaps Uncovered interest rate parity 129 FN2191 Principles of corporate finance Sample examination questions 1. Large businesses spend significant amounts of money annually on insurance. Why? Should they insure against all risks? Does insurance make more sense for some risks than others? 2. A silver-mining firm is concerned about volatility in its revenues. The price of silver is currently $65/ounce, but it is extremely volatile and could fall as low as $63 or rise as high as high as $68 in the next month. The company will bring 100 ounces to the market next month. The one-month interest rate is 0. a. What will be the total revenue if the firm remains unhedged for silver prices of $60, $63, and $68 per ounce? b. The future price of silver for delivery one month ahead is $66. What will be the firm’s total revenues for each silver price if the firm enters into a one-month futures contract to deliver 100 ounces of silver? c. What will total revenues be if the firm buys a one-month put option to sell silver for $65 an ounce? The put option costs $4.5. 3. A catering firm faces a 9 per cent chance of a potential loss of $1 million next year. If the firm purchases new equipment, it can reduce the chance of this loss to 4 per cent, but this new equipment has an upfront cost of $10,000. The beta of the loss is 0, and the risk-free interest rate is 5 per cent. a. If the firm decides to be uninsured, what is the NPV of purchasing the new equipment? b. If the firm decides to insure fully, what is the NPV of purchasing the new equipment? c. Given your answer to part (b), what is the actuarially fair cost of full insurance? d. What is the minimum-size deductible that would leave your firm with an incentive to purchase the new equipment? e. What is the actuarially fair price of insurance with the deductible in part (d)? 130